Skip to main content

Two retailer–supplier supply chain models with default risk under trade credit policy

Abstract

The purpose of the paper is to formulate two uncooperative replenishment models with demand and default risk which are the functions of the trade credit period, i.e., a Nash equilibrium model and a supplier-Stackelberg model. Firstly, we present the optimal results of decentralized decision and centralized decision without trade credit. Secondly, we derive the existence and uniqueness conditions of the optimal solutions under the two games, respectively. Moreover, we present a set of theorems and corollary to determine the optimal solutions. Finally, we provide an example and sensitivity analysis to illustrate the proposed strategy and optimal solutions. Sensitivity analysis reveals that the total profits of supply chain under the two games both are better than the results under the centralized decision only if the optimal trade credit period isn’t too short. It also reveals that the size of trade credit period, demand, retailer’s profit and supplier’s profit have strong relationship with the increasing demand coefficient, wholesale price, default risk coefficient and production cost. The major contribution of the paper is that we comprehensively compare between the results of decentralized decision and centralized decision without trade credit, Nash equilibrium and supplier-Stackelberg models with trade credit, and obtain some interesting managerial insights and practical implications.

Background

In the past 100 years, a huge of extensions of the traditional Economic Order Quantity (EOQ) model has been proposed by lots of researchers. Recently, the International Journal of Production Economics published a special issue “Celebrating a century of the economic order quantity model in honor of Ford Whitman Harris”. Among them, Andriolo et al. (2014) and Glock et al. (2014) respectively adopted different methodologies to analysis the evolution and main streams of these research emerged from Harris’ seminal lot size during 100 years of history and proposed a new research opportunities for future research, such as, sustainability issue and cash flows. Latest works include those by Battini et al. (2014), and Marchi et al. (2016), among others.

One of most important extensions is that incorporating trade credit into the EOQ. It assumes that supplier offers retailer/buyer a permissible delay in payments (trade credit period). The account is not settled during trade credit period and there is no interest charge. In fact, as short-term financing tool, trade credit is widely implemented in fierce competitive circumstance and has important influence on inventory holding cost (Azzi et al. 2014).

Goyal (1985) first fully analysis the impact of fixed permissible delay in payments on the retailer’s ordering decision. Since then, the effect of fixed trade credit on the replenishment policy has been studied in extensive literatures. For instance, Aggarwal and Jaggi (1995) extended Goyal’s model (1985) to consider exponentially deteriorating items. Teng (2002) further established an easy analytical closed-form solution about Goyal’s model (1985) by considering the difference between the purchase cost and the retail price. Furthermore, Huang (2003) proposed a brand new inventory model under two levels of trade credit where the manufacturer offers trade credit to the retailer, and the retailer also offers his or her customer partial trade credit.

Teng et al. (2012a, b) extended the constant demand to a linear increasing demand under trade credit. Wu and Zhao (2015a) recently established an EOQ model with a constant deterioration rate, a current inventory-dependent and linearly increasing time-varying demand under trade credit and presented some fundamental theoretical results. Lots of related articles can be seen in Khouja and Mehrez (1996), Chu et al. (1998), Chang and Dye (2001), Teng and Chang (2009), Jain and Aggarwal (2012), Chung (2013), Zhou et al. (2013), Chen and Teng (2014), Ouyang et al. (2014), among others. However, most of these models assumed that a trade credit period is fixed parameter and the retailer sets up its own strategy only from its individual perspective. Elaborating on this subject, Chang et al. (2008), Seifert et al. (2013), and Molamohamadi et al. (2014) conducted comprehensive literature reviews of different model settings.

On the other hand, like quantity discount, price discount, etc., as a profit transfer means, trade credit has been deeply studied in supply chain coordination. For instance, Yang and Wee (2006) presented a collaborative model for deteriorating items with price-sensitive demand and finite replenishment rate under trade credit and proposed a negotiation factor to share the additional profit between the vendor and buyer. Sarmah et al. (2008) considered the issue of coordination with trade credit term in a single supplier and multiple heterogeneous retailers at same replenishment cycle time. Wu and Zhao (2014a) recently established a collaborative model under trade credit for inventory-dependent and time-varying demand during the finite planning horizon. Other related articles can be seen in Jaber and Osman (2006), Chen and Kang (2007), Huang et al. (2010), Chan et al. (2010), Krichen et al. (2011), Teng et al. (2012a, b), Hsu and Hsu (2013), Wu and Zhao (2014b), Glock and Kim (2015), and Marchi et al. (2016), among others. These papers assumed that trade credit is a decision variable and coordination mechanism, and discussed the effect of trade credit in coordinating supply chain for different settings.

However, how to determinate an optimal trade credit period for the supplier has been received limited attention for a long time. Although, Kim et al. (1995) first proposed a strategy to determine the optimal trade credit period for supplier and the optimal pricing for the retailer in supplier-Stackelberg game. And then, Abad and Jaggi (2003) extended the model of Kim et al. (1995). The two literatures did not arouse scholars’ attention at that time. The question can be really solved until Teng and Lou (2012) proposed the demand rate is an increasing function of the trade credit period (a decision variable). Although, Jaggi et al. (2008) first assumed that trade credit period has a positive impact on demand and set up a polynomial function, where trade credit period is still given parameter. Of course, other researcher also proposed inventory model with demand rate is dependent on the trade credit period, such as, Ho (2011), Giri and Maiti (2013), the trade credit period is constant.

At present, determining optimal trade credit period is being more and more attention from researchers. There are two main research views, one is trade credit provider perspective, and other is game perspective. From trade credit provider perspective, for instance, Lou and Wang (2012) extended Teng and Lou’s model (2012) to establish an EOQ model to derive optimal trade credit period and lot size simultaneously. But, in their model, they didn’t concern the retailer’s benefit and an additional capital opportunity cost the supplier burdens for offering trade credit. Recently, Teng et al. (2014) extended Lou and Wang’s model (2012) to consider learning curve phenomenon and the loss of capital opportunity during the delay payment period. Dye and Yang (2015) further extended Lou and Wang’s model (2012) to include cases with partial backorder and the supplier’s opportunity cost and two carbon emission constraints. Chen and Teng (2015) recently extended Teng and Lou’s model (2012) to consider time-varying deteriorating items and default risk rates under two levels of trade credit by discounted cash flow analysis. Other prominent and latest works include those by Wang et al. (2014), Wu et al. (2014), and Shah and Cárdenas-Barrón (2015), among others.

Determining optimal trade credit period from the game perspective is becoming concerned. Only a few corresponding articles may be found in latest literatures. Zhou et al. (2012) established an uncooperative inventory model for items with stock-dependent demand where the retailer has limited displayed-shelf space, and optimized the trade credit period in a two-echelon supply chain. Zhou and Zhou (2013) investigated two trade credit scenarios, i.e., unconditional and conditional trade credit, and discussed how the supplier sets up trade credit period to minimize his or her cost under supplier-Stackelberg game in a two-echelon supply chain. Based on the models of Zhou and Zhou (2013) and Teng et al. (2014), Wu and Zhao (2015b) established an uncooperative replenishment model with time-varying demand and time-varying price and learning curve phenomenon under finite planning horizon and supplier-Stackelberg game. However, these cited references do not consider the effect of trade credit period on market demand and default risk.

Additionally, based on the achievements of Teng and Lou (2012) and Lou and Wang (2012), Chern et al. (2013) recently established a vendor–buyer Stackelberg equilibrium model with compounded interest rate and relaxing lot-for lot replenishment policy, and derived the vendor’s optimal ordering policy and trade credit period. Chern et al. (2014) extended the model of Chern et al. (2013) to establish a vendor–buyer supply chain model in Nash game. But the two references ignored the results of decentralized decision and centralized decision without trade credit, and didn’t compare with the results of Nash equilibrium and supplier-Stackelberg models with trade credit in detail.

In this paper, we discuss about two retailer–supplier uncooperative replenishment models with trade credit where the demand and default risk are liked to trade credit period, i.e., a Nash equilibrium model and a supplier-Stackelberg model. We comprehensively compare between the results of decentralized decision and centralized decision without trade credit, and Nash game and supplier-Stackelberg models with trade credit. We distinguish the impact of trade credit period on the demand and default risk to observe two parties’ profit and behavior.

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. In “Assumptions and notation” section, assumptions and notation are presented. In “Mathematical formulation of the model without trade credit” section, we present the decentralized and centralized inventory models without trade credit. In “Mathematical formulation of the models with trade credit” section, we derive uncooperative supply chain inventory models with trade credit in Nash game and supplier-Stackelberg game, respectively. In “Numerical examples and analysis” section, we present a numerical example and sensitivity analysis, and propose important conclusions on managerial phenomena. The last section summarizes the paper’s findings and suggests areas for future research.

Assumptions and notation

The following assumptions and notation are used throughout the paper. Some assumptions and notation will be presented later when they are needed.

Assumptions

  1. (i)

    Permissible delay in payments or trade credit attracts new buyers who consider it to be a type of price reduction. According to the previous literatures, such as that by Teng and Lou (2012), Lou and Wang (2012), Chern et al. (2013), and Teng et al. (2014), among other authors, demand rate is assumed to be a polynomial or exponential function of the trade credit period. For convenience, the demand rate D(t) may be given by

    $$D(M) = Ke^{aM} ,$$
    (1)

    where, \(K > 0\), \(a{ \ge }0\).

The basis of the simple demand expression depends on two assumptions. One is the impact of trade credit on the demand, the other is the uncertainty of environment influence on the expectation value of the demand is zero (Jeuland and Shugan, 1983).

  1. (ii)

    The longer the trade credit period is to the retailer, the higher the default risk is to the supplier. The default risk function with respect to trade credit period is given by

    $$F(M) = 1 - e^{ - bM} ,$$
    (2)

    where, \(b{ \ge }0\).

  2. (iii)

    Shortages are not permitted and lead time is zero.

  3. (v)

    The replenishment is instantaneous and the production rate is finite. Furthermore, the demand for the product does not exceed the production rate in model.

  4. (vi)

    The supplier follows a lot-for-lot replenishment policy.

  5. (vii)

    To simplify the problem and obtain main conclusions, we further assume that the retailer’s capital opportunity cost equal to its opportunity gain.

Notation

For convenience, subscript i represents different member, \(i = s\) represents the supplier; \(i = r\) represents the retailer; \(i = sc\) represents the whole supply chain.

A :

the production rate per year for the supplier.

b :

the default risk coefficient.

Ke aM :

the demand rate per year, \(A \ge Ke^{aM}\), \(M_{\rm max} = {{\ln \left( {{A \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {A K}} \right. \kern-0pt} K}} \right)} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{\ln \left( {{A \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {A K}} \right. \kern-0pt} K}} \right)} a}} \right. \kern-0pt} a}\), where, \(K\) the basic demand rate, \(a\) the increasing demand coefficient.

S i :

the setup cost, $/order, \(i = s,r\).

C :

the production cost per unit, $/unit.

W :

the wholesale price per unit, $/unit.

P :

the retail price per unit, $/unit, with \(P > W > C\).

h i :

the inventory holding cost, $/unit/year, \(i = s,r\).

I i :

the interest charged per dollar per year, $/year, \(i = s,r\).

\(\Pi_{i}^{j}\) :

total annual profit. \(i = s,r,sc\), \(j = 0\), 1, 2, 3. \(j = 0\) decentralized decision; \(j = 1\) centralized decision; \(j = 2\) the Nash game; \(j = 3\) the supplier-Stackelberg game.

\(M^{j}\) :

the length of the trade credit period offered by the supplier in years, decision variable, \(j = 2\), 3.

\(Q^{j}\) :

the order quantity, decision variable, \(j = 0\), 1, 2, 3.

Mathematical formulation of the model without trade credit

In this section, we first propose two inventory models without trade credit, i.e., decentralized decision and centralized decision. The corresponding results of the two scenarios will be used as comparison benchmarks when the supplier permits delay in payments to the retailer for supply chain coordination.

Firstly, in the decentralized decision, there is no coordination and no trade credit between the supplier and the retailer. Therefore, the demand rate is constant \(K\). The retailer adopts the classic EOQ solution to optimize its total profit or total cost. The optimal economic order quantity (EOQ) of the retailer is given by

$$Q^{0*} = \sqrt {2KS_{r} /h_{r} } ,$$
(3)

and the optimal annual profit of the retailer is

$$\Pi_{r}^{0} = \left( {P - W} \right)K - \sqrt {2KS_{r} h_{r} } .$$
(4)

When the retailer orders \(Q^{0*}\), the supplier will produce lot size \(Q^{0*}\) and instantaneously replenishes the retailer according to the lot-for-lot policy. Therefore, the supplier’s total annual profit is expressed as

$$\Pi_{s}^{0} = \left( {W - C} \right)K - S_{s} \sqrt {Kh_{r} /2S_{r} } - Kh_{s} \sqrt {KS_{r} /2h_{r} } /A.$$
(5)

Consequently, the total annual profit of the supply chain is given by

$$\Pi_{sc}^{0} = \left( {P - C} \right)K - \sqrt {2KS_{r} h_{r} } - S_{s} \sqrt {Kh_{r} /2S_{r} } - Kh_{s} \sqrt {KS_{r} /2h_{r} } /A.$$
(6)

Secondly, in the centralized decision, the supplier and the retailer are willing to collaborate and form a vertical alliance or virtual integrated firm. They will jointly decide the replenishment schedule. For no trade credit, the demand rate is still constant, \(K\). In this way, the joint total annual profit for the whole supply chain is

$$\Pi_{sc}^{1} (Q) = \left( {P - C} \right)K - K\left( {S_{r} + S_{s} } \right)/Q - Qh_{r} /2 - KQh_{s} /2A.$$
(7)

Therefore, the optimal joint order quantity of the supply chain is given by

$$Q^{1*} = \sqrt {2AK\left( {S_{r} + S_{s} } \right)/\left( {Ah_{r} + Kh_{s} } \right)} .$$
(8)

The optimal annual profit of the supply chain responding to lot size \(Q^{1*}\) will be

$$\Pi_{sc}^{1} = \left( {P - C} \right)K - \sqrt {2K\left( {S_{r} + S_{s} } \right)\left( {Ah_{r} + Kh_{s} } \right)/A} .$$
(9)

Mathematical formulation of the models with trade credit

According to the assumptions (i) and (ii), the supplier’s expected net revenue with default risk is \(WD(M)\left( {1 - F(M)} \right) = WKe^{{\left( {a - b} \right)M}}\). Additionally, he or she will burden an additional capital opportunity cost, i.e., \(CKe^{aM} I_{s} M\), for offering trade credit period \(M\) to the retailer. Meanwhile, for the retailer, he or she can save an additional capital opportunity cost \(WKe^{aM} I_{r} M\). Therefore, the retailer’s and the supplier’s total annual profits can be expressed as

$$\Pi_{r}^{2} (Q) = \Pi_{r}^{3} (Q) = \left( {P - W} \right)Ke^{aM} - S_{r} Ke^{aM} /Q - Qh_{r} /2 + WKe^{aM} I_{r} M,$$
(10)
$$\Pi_{s}^{2} (M) = \Pi_{s}^{3} (M) = WKe^{{\left( {a - b} \right)M}} - CKe^{aM} - \frac{{Ke^{aM} S_{s} }}{Q} - \frac{{Ke^{aM} h_{s} Q}}{2A} - CKe^{aM} I_{s} M,$$
(11)

respectively.

Two parties’ decision making in Nash game

In this subsection, we assume that the supplier and the retailer have the same bargaining power, i.e., neither side has the monopoly strength. Under this background, the optimal equilibrium solution is Nash equilibrium.

From the view of Nash game, the first derivative condition of \(\Pi_{r}^{2} (Q)\) with respect to \(Q\) and the first derivative condition of \(\Pi_{s}^{2} (M)\) with respect to \(M\) should be established simultaneously. Therefore, the first derivative \({{d\Pi_{r}^{2} (Q)} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{d\Pi_{r}^{2} (Q)} {dQ}}} \right. \kern-0pt} {dQ}}\) and the first derivative \(d\Pi_{s}^{2} (M)/dM\) will be given by

$$d\Pi_{r}^{2} (Q)/dQ = S_{r} Ke^{aM} /Q^{2} - h_{r} /2,$$
(12)
$$\frac{{d\Pi_{s}^{2} (M)}}{dM} = \left( {a - b} \right)WKe^{{\left( {a - b} \right)M}} - aCKe^{aM} - \frac{{aKe^{aM} S_{s} }}{Q} - \frac{{aKe^{aM} h_{s} Q}}{2A} - CKe^{aM} I_{s} - aCKe^{aM} I_{s} M.$$
(13)

First, by the first derivative condition \(d\Pi_{r}^{2} (Q)/dQ = 0\), the optimal ordering lot size in Nash game is given by

$$Q^{2*} = \sqrt {2S_{r} Ke^{aM} /h_{r} } .$$
(14)

Next, substituting \(Q^{2*} = \sqrt {2S_{r} Ke^{aM} /h_{r} }\) into Eq. (13), the \(d\Pi_{s}^{2} (M)/dM\) may be reduced to

$$\frac{{d\Pi_{s}^{2} (M)}}{dM} = \left( {a - b} \right)WKe^{{\left( {a - b} \right)M}} - aCKe^{aM} - aS_{s} \sqrt {\frac{{h_{r} Ke^{aM} }}{{2S_{r} }}} - \frac{{aKe^{aM} h_{s} }}{A}\sqrt {\frac{{S_{r} Ke^{aM} }}{{2h_{r} }}} - CKe^{aM} I_{s} - aCKe^{aM} I_{s} M.$$
(15)

It includes a single decision variable \(M\).

Theorem 1

The supplier’s optimal trade credit period is zero (i.e., \(M^{2*} = 0\) ) if (i) \(a \le b\) , or (ii) \((a - b)W \le aC\) , or (iii) \((a - b)W \le aC + CI_{s}\).

Proof

From Eq. (15), if \(a \le b\), \(\frac{{d\Pi_{s}^{2} (M)}}{dM} < 0\). Consequently, the optimal trade credit period is zero, i.e., \(M^{2*} = 0\). Similarly, if \((a - b)W \le aC\), or \((a - b)W \le aC + CI_{s}\), we have the same results \(\frac{{d\Pi_{s}^{2} (M)}}{dM} < 0\), and \(M^{2*} = 0\). This completes the proof.

Consequently, the retailer’s and the supplier’s total annual profits are given by

$$\Pi_{r}^{2} (\text{M}^{{\text{2*}}} = 0) = \left( {P - W} \right)K - \sqrt {2KS_{r} h_{r} } = \Pi_{r}^{0} ,$$
(16)
$$\Pi_{s}^{2} (\text{M}^{{\text{2*}}} = 0) = \left( {W - C} \right)K - S_{s} \sqrt {{{Kh_{r} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{Kh_{r} } {2S_{r} }}} \right. \kern-0pt} {2S_{r} }}} - {{Kh_{s} \sqrt {{{KS_{r} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{KS_{r} } {2h_{r} }}} \right. \kern-0pt} {2h_{r} }}} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{Kh_{s} \sqrt {{{KS_{r} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{KS_{r} } {2h_{r} }}} \right. \kern-0pt} {2h_{r} }}} } A}} \right. \kern-0pt} A} = \Pi_{s}^{0} .$$
(17)

That is to say, the two parties don’t achieve any coordination or improvement in Theorem 1.

Next, we discuss the another condition, i.e., \((a - b)W > aC + CI_{s}\). By the first derivative condition \({{d\Pi_{s}^{2} (M)} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{d\Pi_{s}^{2} (M)} {dM = 0}}} \right. \kern-0pt} {dM = 0}}\), we can obtain

$$\left( {a - b} \right)We^{ - bM} - aC - aS_{s} \sqrt {\frac{{h_{r} }}{{2S_{r} Ke^{aM} }}} - \frac{{ah_{s} }}{A}\sqrt {\frac{{S_{r} Ke^{aM} }}{{2h_{r} }}} - CI_{s} - aCI_{s} M = 0.$$
(18)

From Eq. (18), the optimal trade credit period function is given by

$$M^{{2\bar{*}}} = {{\left\{ {\left( {a - b} \right)We^{{ - bM^{{2\bar{*}}} }} - aC - aS_{s} \sqrt {\frac{{h_{r} }}{{2S_{r} Ke^{{aM^{{2\bar{*}}} }} }}} - \frac{{ah_{s} }}{A}\sqrt {\frac{{S_{r} Ke^{{aM^{{2\bar{*}}} }} }}{{2h_{r} }}} - CI_{s} } \right\}} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{\left\{ {\left( {a - b} \right)We^{{ - bM^{{2\bar{*}}} }} - aC - aS_{s} \sqrt {\frac{{h_{r} }}{{2S_{r} Ke^{{aM^{{2\bar{*}}} }} }}} - \frac{{ah_{s} }}{A}\sqrt {\frac{{S_{r} Ke^{{aM^{{2\bar{*}}} }} }}{{2h_{r} }}} - CI_{s} } \right\}} {aCI_{s} }}} \right. \kern-0pt} {aCI_{s} }},$$
(19)
$${\text{when}}\;\left( {a - b} \right)We^{{ - bM^{{2\bar{*}}} }} - aC - aS_{s} \sqrt {\frac{{h_{r} }}{{2S_{r} Ke^{{aM^{{2\bar{*}}} }} }}} - \frac{{ah_{s} }}{A}\sqrt {\frac{{S_{r} Ke^{{aM^{{2\bar{*}}} }} }}{{2h_{r} }}} - CI_{s} > 0.$$

Note that the left and right sides of Eq. (19) are functions of \(M\). Due to the complexity of the problem, it seems difficult to derive a closed-form expression. Additionally, in Eq. (19), we obviously observe that the left side increases and the right side decreases as \(M\) increases. There is only one intersection point when the two sides of Eq. (19) intersect, i.e., unique optimal positive solution \(M^{{2\bar{*}}}\).

Theorem 2

When \(\left( {a - b} \right)W - aC - CI_{s} - aS_{s} \sqrt {\frac{{h_{r} }}{{2S_{r} K}}} - \frac{{ah_{s} }}{A}\sqrt {\frac{{S_{r} K}}{{2h_{r} }}} > 0\) , (i) if \(M^{{2\bar{*}}} < M_{\rm max}\) , the final optimal trade credit period is \(M^{2*} = M^{{2\bar{*}}}\) ; (ii) if \(M^{{2\bar{*}}} \ge M_{\rm max}\) , the final optimal trade credit period is \(M^{2*} = M_{\rm max}\).

Proof

Firstly, according to \(\left( {a - b} \right)W - aC - CI_{s} - aS_{s} \sqrt {\frac{{h_{r} }}{{2S_{r} K}}} - \frac{{ah_{s} }}{A}\sqrt {\frac{{S_{r} K}}{{2h_{r} }}} > 0\), we can obtain that

$$\frac{{d\Pi_{s}^{2} (M)}}{dM}\left| {_{M = 0}^{{}} } \right. = (a - b)WK - aCK - aS_{s} \sqrt {\frac{{h_{r} K}}{{2S_{r} }}} - \frac{{aKh_{s} }}{A}\sqrt {\frac{{S_{r} K}}{{2h_{r} }}} - CKI_{s} > 0,$$
(20)
$$\frac{{d\Pi_{s}^{2} (M)}}{dM}\left| {_{M \to \infty }^{{}} } \right. = - \infty .$$
(21)

Additionally, applying the second derivative of \(\Pi_{s}^{2} (M)\) with respect to \(M\), we have

$$\frac{{d^{2} \Pi_{s}^{2} (M)}}{{dM^{2} }} = \left[ {(a - b)^{2} We^{ - bM} - a^{2} C - \frac{{3a^{2} h_{s} }}{2A}\sqrt {\frac{{S_{r} Ke^{aM} }}{{2h_{r} }}} - 2aCI_{s} } \right]Ke^{aM} - a^{2} S_{s} \sqrt {\frac{{h_{r} Ke^{aM} }}{{8S_{r} }}} - a^{2} CKe^{aM} I_{s} M.$$
(22)

Next, we have two alternative cases: (i) \((a - b)^{2} W - a^{2} C - \frac{{3a^{2} h_{s} }}{2A}\sqrt {\frac{{S_{r} K}}{{2h_{r} }}} - 2aCI_{s} \le 0\) and (ii) \((a - b)^{2} W - a^{2} C - \frac{{3a^{2} h_{s} }}{2A}\sqrt {\frac{{S_{r} K}}{{2h_{r} }}} - 2aCI_{s} > 0\).

Case 1

\((a - b)^{2} W - a^{2} C - \frac{{3a^{2} h_{s} }}{2A}\sqrt {\frac{{S_{r} K}}{{2h_{r} }}} - 2aCI_{s} \le 0\).

In this case, we know that \((a - b)^{2} We^{ - bM} - a^{2} C - \frac{{3a^{2} h_{s} }}{2A}\sqrt {\frac{{S_{r} Ke^{aM} }}{{2h_{r} }}} - 2aCI_{s} < 0\), further, \(\frac{{d^{2} \Pi_{s}^{2} (M)}}{{dM^{2} }} < 0\). Therefore, \(\Pi_{s}^{2} (M)\) is a strictly concave function in \(\left[ {0,\infty } \right)\). Therefore, combining with Eq. (20) and Eq. (21), we know that there exists a unique positive optimal solution such that \(\frac{{d\Pi_{s}^{2} (M)}}{dM} = 0\), denoted as \(M^{{2\bar{*}}}\).

Case 2

\((a - b)^{2} W - a^{2} C - \frac{{3a^{2} h_{s} }}{2A}\sqrt {\frac{{S_{r} K}}{{2h_{r} }}} - 2aCI_{s} > 0\)

In this case, we know that the value of \(\frac{{d^{2} \Pi_{s}^{2} (M)}}{{dM^{2} }}\) moves from positive to negative as \(M\) increases, that is to say, \(\Pi_{s}^{2} (M)\) is a convex-concave function of \(M\). Therefore, combining with Eq. (20) and Eq. (21), we know that \(\Pi_{s}^{2} (M)\) is a unimodal function in \(\left[ {0,\infty } \right)\). There also exists a unique positive optimal solution such that \(\frac{{d\Pi_{s}^{2} (M)}}{dM} = 0\), denoted as \(M^{{2\bar{*}}}\).

In a word, if \(\left( {a - b} \right)W - aC - CI_{s} - aS_{s} \sqrt {\frac{{h_{r} }}{{2S_{r} K}}} - \frac{{ah_{s} }}{A}\sqrt {\frac{{S_{r} K}}{{2h_{r} }}} > 0\), the solution of Eq. (19) is a unique optimal positive solution \(M^{{2\bar{*}}}\) for \(\Pi_{s}^{2} (M)\). Then, we consider the upper bound of \(M\), i.e., \(M_{\rm max}\). If \(M^{{2\bar{*}}} < M_{\rm max}\), the final optimal trade credit period is \(M^{2*} = M^{{2\bar{*}}}\). If \(M^{{2\bar{*}}} \ge M_{\rm max}\), the final optimal trade credit period is \(M^{2*} = M_{\rm max}\). This completes the proof.

From Eq. (19) and Theorem 2, we obtain the following results.

Corollary 1

(i) A higher value of \(a\), \(W\), \(A\) and a lower value of \(b\), \(C\), \(S_{s}\), \(h_{s}\), \(I_{s}\) cause a higher value of \(\left( {a - b} \right)W - aC - CI_{s} - aS_{s} \sqrt {\frac{{h_{r} }}{{2S_{r} K}}} - \frac{{ah_{s} }}{A}\sqrt {\frac{{S_{r} K}}{{2h_{r} }}}\), and \(M^{{2\bar{*}}}\).

(ii) The change of \(P\) and \(I_{r}\), i.e., the retailer’s profit parameters, do not affect the supplier as to whether to offer trade credit to the retailer.

Proof

The above is apparent from \(\left( {a - b} \right)W - aC - CI_{s} - aS_{s} \sqrt {\frac{{h_{r} }}{{2S_{r} K}}} - \frac{{ah_{s} }}{A}\sqrt {\frac{{S_{r} K}}{{2h_{r} }}} > 0\), Eq. (19) and Theorem 2.

A simple economic interpretation is as follows. A higher value of \(a\) (i.e., increasing demand coefficient) leads to a higher demand, and higher values of \(W\) and \(A\) lead to higher revenue. Hence, the supplier is willing to offer a longer trade credit period. On the other hand, lower values of \(b\) (i.e., default risk coefficient) and \(C\) lead to a higher expected revenue for supplier, and lower values of \(S_{s}\), \(h_{s}\), and \(I_{s}\) lead to a lower ordering and inventory cost. Hence, the supplier willing to offer a longer trade credit period to the retailer.

Furthermore, according to Theorem 2, Theorem 1 can be modified to Theorem 3.

Theorem 3

The supplier’s optimal trade credit period is zero (i.e., \(M^{2*} = 0\) ) if (i) \(a \le b\) , or (ii) \((a - b)W \le aC\) , or (iii) \((a - b)W \le aC + CI_{s}\) , or (iv) \(\left( {a - b} \right)W - aC - CI_{s} - aS_{s} \sqrt {\frac{{h_{r} }}{{2S_{r} K}}} - \frac{{ah_{s} }}{A}\sqrt {\frac{{S_{r} K}}{{2h_{r} }}} \le 0\).

Corollary 2

The supplier’s optimal trade credit period is zero (i.e., \(M^{2*} = 0\) ) if \(\left( {a - b} \right)W - aC - CI_{s} - a\sqrt {\frac{{S_{s} h_{s} }}{A}} \le 0\).

Proof

We use the theorem that the arithmetic mean is not always less than the geometric mean. It is omitted.

In a word, the retailer’s and the supplier’s final total annual profits in Nash game are given by

$$\Pi_{r}^{2} (M^{2*} ) = \left( {P - W} \right)Ke^{{aM^{2*} }} - \sqrt {2S_{r} h_{r} Ke^{{aM^{2*} }} } + WKe^{{aM^{2*} }} I_{r} M^{2*} ,$$
(23)
$$\Pi_{s}^{2} (M^{2*} ) = WKe^{{\left( {a - b} \right)M^{2*} }} - CKe^{{aM^{2*} }} - S_{s} \sqrt {\frac{{Ke^{{aM^{2*} }} h_{r} }}{{2S_{r} }}} - \frac{{Ke^{{aM^{2*} }} h_{s} }}{A}\sqrt {\frac{{Ke^{{aM^{2*} }} S_{r} }}{{2h_{r} }}} - CKe^{{aM^{2*} }} I_{s} M^{2*} ,$$
(24)

respectively.

Note that \(\Pi_{r}^{2} (M^{2*} )\) is an increasing function of \(M^{2*}\) only if \(\Pi_{r}^{0} \ge 0\), which is a reasonable assumption. That is to say, as long as the trade credit period is offered by the supplier, \(\Pi_{r}^{2} (M^{2*} )\) is greater than \(\Pi_{r}^{0}\), i.e., \(\Pi_{r}^{2} (M^{2*} ) \ge \Pi_{r}^{0}\). Additionally, it is obvious that \(\Pi_{s}^{2} (M^{2*} ) \ge \Pi_{s}^{0}\). Proof is omitted.

Two parties’ decision making in a supplier-Stackelberg game

In this subsection, we suppose that the supplier is the dominating company over the retailer. For example, a supplier, such as Siwin Foods, (a famous food manufacturer in China) has a dominate power over its downstream small store. Consequently, the dominating company (e.g., Siwin Foods) acts as a leader, its downstream small store acts as a follower, which call a supplier-Stackelberg game. In a supplier-Stackelberg game, the supplier offers a trade credit period \(M\), and then the retailer maximizes his or her own profit to find optimal ordering lot size, next, the supplier observes the retailer’s optimal solution as a function of \(M\), finally, he or she find the optimal \(M\).

  • (i) The retailer’s optimal response

Firstly, we should know how the retailer responds to any trade credit period \(M\) offered by the supplier. By the first derivative necessary condition \({{d\Pi_{r}^{3} (Q)} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{d\Pi_{r}^{3} (Q)} {dQ = 0}}} \right. \kern-0pt} {dQ = 0}}\), the optimal ordering lot size in a supplier-Stackelberg game is given by

$$Q^{3*} = \sqrt {{{2S_{r} Ke^{aM} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{2S_{r} Ke^{aM} } {h_{r} }}} \right. \kern-0pt} {h_{r} }}},$$
(25)

which is a function of \(M\).

  • (ii) The supplier’s optimization

After observing the optimal response of the retailer (given by Eq. (25)), the supplier selects optimal \(M\) so that his or her total annual profit is maximized.

Therefore, substituting \(Q^{3*} = \sqrt {{{2S_{r} Ke^{aM} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{2S_{r} Ke^{aM} } {h_{r} }}} \right. \kern-0pt} {h_{r} }}}\) into Eq. (11), the \(\Pi_{s}^{3} (M)\) can be modified to a new function of \(M\) will be given by

$$\Pi_{s}^{3} (M) = WKe^{{\left( {a - b} \right)M}} - CKe^{aM} - S_{s} \sqrt {\frac{{h_{r} Ke^{aM} }}{{2S_{r} }}} - \frac{{Ke^{aM} h_{s} }}{2A}\sqrt {\frac{{2Ke^{aM} S_{r} }}{{h_{r} }}} - CKe^{aM} I_{s} M.$$
(26)

In order to maximize \(\Pi_{s}^{3} (M)\) in Eq. (26), we obtain

$$\frac{{d\Pi_{s}^{3} (M)}}{dM} = \left( {a - b} \right)WKe^{{\left( {a - b} \right)M}} - aCKe^{aM} - \frac{{aS_{s} }}{2}\sqrt {\frac{{h_{r} Ke^{aM} }}{{2S_{r} }}} - \frac{{3ah_{s} Ke^{aM} }}{2A}\sqrt {\frac{{S_{r} Ke^{aM} }}{{2h_{r} }}} - CKe^{aM} I_{s} - aCKe^{aM} I_{s} M$$
(27)

Theorem 4

The supplier’s optimal trade credit period is zero (i.e., \(M^{3*} = 0\) ) if (i) \(a \le b\) , or (ii) \((a - b)W \le aC\) , or (iii) \((a - b)W \le aC + CI_{s}\).

Proof

We omit the proof of Theorem 4 since it mimics that of Theorem 1.

Consequently, the retailer’s and the supplier’s total annual profits are given by

$$\Pi_{r}^{3} (M^{3*} = 0) = \left( {P - W} \right)K - \sqrt {2KS_{r} h_{r} } = \Pi_{r}^{0} ,$$
(28)
$$\Pi_{s}^{3} (M^{3*} = 0) = \left( {W - C} \right)K - S_{s} \sqrt {{{Kh_{r} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{Kh_{r} } {2S_{r} }}} \right. \kern-0pt} {2S_{r} }}} - {{Kh_{s} \sqrt {{{KS_{r} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{KS_{r} } {2h_{r} }}} \right. \kern-0pt} {2h_{r} }}} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{Kh_{s} \sqrt {{{KS_{r} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{KS_{r} } {2h_{r} }}} \right. \kern-0pt} {2h_{r} }}} } A}} \right. \kern-0pt} A} = \Pi_{s}^{0} .$$
(29)

That is to say, the two parties don’t achieve any coordination or improvement in Theorem 4.

Next, we discuss the another condition, i.e., \((a - b)W > aC + CI_{s}\). By the first derivative condition \({{d\Pi_{s}^{3} (M)} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{d\Pi_{s}^{3} (M)} {dM = 0}}} \right. \kern-0pt} {dM = 0}}\), we obtain

$$\left( {a - b} \right)We^{ - bM} - aC - \frac{{aS_{s} }}{2}\sqrt {\frac{{h_{r} }}{{2S_{r} Ke^{aM} }}} - \frac{{3ah_{s} }}{2A}\sqrt {\frac{{S_{r} Ke^{aM} }}{{2h_{r} }}} - CI_{s} - aCI_{s} M = 0.$$
(30)

From Eq. (30), the optimal trade credit period function is given by

$$M^{{3\bar{*}}} = {{\left\{ {\left( {a - b} \right)We^{{ - bM^{{3\bar{*}}} }} - aC - \frac{{aS_{s} }}{2}\sqrt {\frac{{h_{r} }}{{2S_{r} Ke^{{aM^{{3\bar{*}}} }} }}} - \frac{{3ah_{s} }}{2A}\sqrt {\frac{{S_{r} Ke^{{aM^{{3\bar{*}}} }} }}{{2h_{r} }}} - CI_{s} } \right\}} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{\left\{ {\left( {a - b} \right)We^{{ - bM^{{3\bar{*}}} }} - aC - \frac{{aS_{s} }}{2}\sqrt {\frac{{h_{r} }}{{2S_{r} Ke^{{aM^{{3\bar{*}}} }} }}} - \frac{{3ah_{s} }}{2A}\sqrt {\frac{{S_{r} Ke^{{aM^{{3\bar{*}}} }} }}{{2h_{r} }}} - CI_{s} } \right\}} {aCI_{s} }}} \right. \kern-0pt} {aCI_{s} }},$$
(31)
$${\text{when}}\;\left( {a - b} \right)We^{{ - bM^{{3\bar{*}}} }} - aC - \frac{{aS_{s} }}{2}\sqrt {\frac{{h_{r} }}{{2S_{r} Ke^{{aM^{{3\bar{*}}} }} }}} - \frac{{3ah_{s} }}{2A}\sqrt {\frac{{S_{r} Ke^{{aM^{{3\bar{*}}} }} }}{{2h_{r} }}} - CI_{s} > 0.$$

Theorem 5

When \(\left( {a - b} \right)W - aC - CI_{s} - \frac{{aS_{s} }}{2}\sqrt {\frac{{h_{r} }}{{2S_{r} K}}} - \frac{{3ah_{s} }}{2A}\sqrt {\frac{{S_{r} K}}{{2h_{r} }}} > 0\) , (i) if \(M^{{3\bar{*}}} < M_{\rm max}\) , the final optimal trade credit period is \(M^{3*} = M^{{3\bar{*}}}\) ; (ii) if \(M^{{3\bar{*}}} \ge M_{\rm max}\) , the final optimal trade credit period is \(M^{3*} = M_{\rm max}\).

Proof

We omit the proof of Theorem 5 since it mimics that of Theorem 2.

From Eq. (31) and Theorem 5, we can obtain the following results.

Corollary 3

  • (i) A higher value of \(a\), \(W\), \(A\) and a lower value of \(b\), \(C\), \(S_{s}\), \(h_{s}\), \(I_{s}\) cause a higher value of \(\left( {a - b} \right)W - aC - CI_{s} - \frac{{aS_{s} }}{2}\sqrt {\frac{{h_{r} }}{{2S_{r} K}}} - \frac{{3ah_{s} }}{2A}\sqrt {\frac{{S_{r} K}}{{2h_{r} }}}\) and \(M^{{3\bar{*}}}\).

  • (ii) The change of \(P\) and \(I_{r}\), i.e., the retailer’s profit parameters, do not affect the supplier as to whether to offer trade credit to the retailer.

Proof

It is omitted.

Likewise, according to Theorem 5, Theorem 4 can be modified to Theorem 6.

Theorem 6

The supplier’s optimal trade credit period is zero (i.e., \(\Pi_{r}^{3} (M^{3*} ) \ge \Pi_{r}^{0}\) ) if (i) \(a \le b\) , or (ii) \((a - b)W \le aC\) , or (iii) \((a - b)W \le aC + CI_{s}\) , or (iv) \(\left( {a - b} \right)W - aC - CI_{s} - \frac{{aS_{s} }}{2}\sqrt {\frac{{h_{r} }}{{2S_{r} K}}} - \frac{{3ah_{s} }}{2A}\sqrt {\frac{{S_{r} K}}{{2h_{r} }}} \le 0\).

Corollary 4

The supplier’s optimal trade credit period is zero (i.e., \(M^{3*} = 0\) ) if \(\left( {a - b} \right)W - aC - CI_{s} - a\sqrt {\frac{{3S_{s} h_{s} }}{4A}} \le 0\).

Proof

It is omitted.

Consequently, the retailer’s and the supplier’s final total annual profits in a supplier-Stackelberg game are given by

$$\Pi_{r}^{3} (M^{3*} ) = \left( {P - W} \right)Ke^{{aM^{3*} }} - \sqrt {2S_{r} h_{r} Ke^{{aM^{3*} }} } + WKe^{{aM^{3*} }} I_{r} M^{3*} ,$$
(32)
$$\Pi_{s}^{3} (M^{3*} ) = WKe^{{\left( {a - b} \right)M^{3*} }} - CKe^{{aM^{3*} }} - S_{s} \sqrt {\frac{{Ke^{{aM^{3*} }} h_{r} }}{{2S_{r} }}} - \frac{{Ke^{{aM^{3*} }} h_{s} }}{A}\sqrt {\frac{{Ke^{{aM^{3*} }} S_{r} }}{{2h_{r} }}} - CKe^{{aM^{3*} }} I_{s} M^{3*} ,$$
(33)

respectively.

Likewize, \(\Pi_{r}^{3} (M^{3*} )\) is an increasing function of \(M^{3*}\) only if \(\Pi_{r}^{0} \ge 0\). Therefore, as long as the trade credit period is offered by the supplier, \(\Pi_{r}^{3} (M^{3*} )\) is greater than \(\Pi_{r}^{0}\), i.e., \(\Pi_{r}^{3} (M^{3*} ) \ge \Pi_{r}^{0}\). Additionally, it is obvious that \(\Pi_{s}^{3} (M^{3*} ) \ge \Pi_{s}^{0}\). Proof is omitted.

Numerical examples and analysis

According to the analysis and arguments in Sect. 4, when the final optimal trade credit period is zero, the retailer’s and the supplier’s total annual profits will not be improved. Therefore, the following numerical example is proposed to illustrate the improvement process for the two games.

Example

Given \(A = 10000\) units/year, \(K = 3600\) units/year, \(a = 1\), \(b = 0.3\), \(P = \$ 35\)/unit, \(W = \$ 23\)/unit, \(C = \$ 12\)/unit, \(S_{r}\) = $200/order, \(h_{r} = \$ 5\)/unit/year, \(I_{r} = 0.12\)/year, \(S_{s}\) = $300/setup, \(h_{s} = \$ 4.5\)/unit/year, \(I_{s} = 0.1\)/year, respectively.

By applying the corresponding expressions, the results are obtained as follow.

In the decentralized decision, the economic order quantity \(Q^{0*} = 537\) units, \(\Pi_{r}^{0} = \$ 40517\)/year, \(\Pi_{s}^{0} = \$ 37153\)/year, the annual profit of the supply chain \(\Pi_{sc}^{0} = \$ 77670\)/year.

In the centralized decision, the optimal joint order quantity \(Q^{1*} = 737\) units. The optimal annual profit of the supply chain \(\Pi_{sc}^{1} = \$ 77918\)/year.

In Nash game, we obtain \(\left( {a - b} \right)W - aC - CI_{s} - aS_{s} \sqrt {\frac{{h_{r} }}{{2S_{r} K}}} - \frac{{ah_{s} }}{A}\sqrt {\frac{{S_{r} K}}{{2h_{r} }}} = 2.22 > 0\). Consequently, \(M^{{2\bar{*}}} = 0.3989\) years \(= 145\) days, and \(M_{\rm max} = 1.0217\) years. According to Theorem 2, for \(M_{\rm max} > M^{{2\bar{*}}}\), the final optimal trade credit period \(M^{2*} = M^{{2\bar{*}}} = 0.3989\) years. Consequently, \(Q^{2*} = 655\) units; \(D^{2} = 5365\) units/year, an increase of 49.03 % (\(\frac{5365 - 3600}{3600}*100\,\% = 49.03\,\%\)); \(\Pi_{\text{r}}^{2} (M^{2*} ) = \$ 67010\)/year, an increase of 65.39 % (\(\frac{67010 - 40517}{40517}*100\,\% = 65.39\,\%\)) from the decentralized decision; \(\Pi_{\text{s}}^{2} (M^{2*} ) = \$ 39279\)/year, an increase of 5.72 % (\(\frac{39279 - 37153}{37153}*100\,\% = 5.72\,\%\)) from the decentralized decision; \(\Pi_{\text{sc}}^{2} (M^{2*} ) = \$ 106289\)/year, an increase of 36.41 % (\(\frac{106289 - 77918}{77918}*100\,\% = 36.41\,\%\)) from the centralized decision. However, we notice that the default risk is \({\text{F}}^{ 2} = 11.3\,\%\).

In a supplier-Stackelberg game, we obtain \(\left( {a - b} \right)W - aC - CI_{s} - \frac{{aS_{s} }}{2}\sqrt {\frac{{h_{r} }}{{2S_{r} K}}} - \frac{{3ah_{s} }}{2A}\sqrt {\frac{{S_{r} K}}{{2h_{r} }}} = 2.44 > 0\). Consequently, \(M^{{3\bar{*}}} = 0.4273\) years \(= 156\) days. According to Theorem 5, for \(M_{\rm max} > M^{{3\bar{*}}}\), the final optimal trade credit period \(M^{3*} = M^{{3\bar{*}}} = 0.4273\) years. Consequently, \(Q^{3*} = 664\) units/order; \(D^{3} = 5519\) units/year, an increase of 53.31 %; \(\Pi_{\text{r}}^{3} (M^{3*} ) = \$ 69420\)/year, an increase of 71.34 % from the decentralized decision; \(\Pi_{\text{s}}^{3} (M^{3*} ) = \$ 39291\)/year, an increase of 5.75 % from the decentralized decision; \(\Pi_{\text{sc}}^{3} (M^{3*} ) = \$ 108711\)/year, an increase of 39.97 % from the centralized decision. However, default risk is \({\text{F}}^{ 3} = 12\, \%\).

For gain more management insights, we present the sensitivity analysis to study the effects of changes in the values of parameters on the optimal values. The basic parameter values are the same as those in the Example. The computational results are given in Table 1. In addition, in order to better understanding, for a, W, b and \(C\), the partial results of the sensitivity analysis have been graphed in Figs. 1, 2, 3 and 4 based on the data in Table 1. The rest of the results in Table 1 are not represented graphically, because the different is very small between the corresponding results of Nash game and supplier-Stackelberg game under the same conditions.

Table 1 The sensitivity analysis on parameters (Note that \(M^{j*}\) is in days, \(F^{j}\) is in percentage)
Fig. 1
figure 1

Influence of the increasing demand coefficient a on the optimal values

Fig. 2
figure 2

Influence of the wholesale price W on the optimal values

Fig. 3
figure 3

Influence of the default risk coefficient b on the optimal values

Fig. 4
figure 4

Influence of the production cost C on the optimal values

The sensitivity analysis reveals the following.

(i) \(M^{2*}\), \(F^{2}\), \(D^{2}\), \(\Pi_{r}^{2}\), \(\Pi_{s}^{2}\), \(M^{3*}\), \(F^{3}\), \(D^{3}\), \(\Pi_{r}^{3}\), \(\Pi_{s}^{3}\) increase as a, \(A\) and \(W\) increase, and decrease as \(b\), \(C\), \(S_{s}\), \(h_{s}\) and \(I_{s}\) increase. This coincides with the Corollary 1 and Corollary3, and the purpose of two games. Note that \(M^{j*} = 0\) or \(M^{j*} = M{}_{\rm max}\)(\(j = 2\), 3), the conclusion is invalid.

(ii) \(M^{2*}\), \(F^{2}\), \(D^{2}\), \(\Pi_{r}^{2}\), \(\Pi_{s}^{2}\), \(M^{3*}\), \(F^{3}\), \(D^{3}\), \(\Pi_{r}^{3}\), \(\Pi_{s}^{3}\) are high sensitive to a, \(W\), \(b\) and \(C\), moderate sensitive to \(S_{s}\) and \(I_{s}\), low sensitive or insensitive to \(A\) and \(h_{s}\). On the one hand, the result shows that the change of trade credit period is greatly influenced by increasing demand coefficient \(a\), default risk coefficient \(b\), wholesale price \(W\), and production cost \(C\). Hence, the two parties should make joint promotional effort to improve the value of \(a\), and to reduce the value of \(b\), such that lead to higher the demand and higher the two parties revenue. Meanwhile, the supplier should strive to reduce the production costs \(C\) through a variety of efficient measures, or raise the wholesale price \(W\). Both of strategies can incentive the supplier to willing to offer a longer trade credit period to raise the profit of the retailer and the supplier. On the other hand, the result also imply that some errors in estimating \(A\) and \(h_{s}\) may result in little deviation from the optimal results. Hence, in practice, the supplier does not have too high surplus production capacity, and does not need to accurately estimate on the inventory holding cost \(h_{s}\).

(iii) For the same conditions, the profits of the retailer, the supplier, and supply chain in a supplier-Stackelberg game are better than the results in Nash game, i.e., \(\Pi_{r}^{3} > \Pi_{r}^{2}\), \(\Pi_{s}^{3} > \Pi_{s}^{2}\), and \(\Pi_{sc}^{3} > \Pi_{sc}^{2}\) in the sensitivity analysis. This is because the optimal trade credit period \(M^{3*}\) is greater than \(M^{2*}\), such that the market demand from supplier-Stackelberg game is greater than from Nash game, i.e., \(D^{3} > D^{2}\). However, we find that the supplier will burden higher default risk in a supplier-Stackelberg game, i.e., \(F^{3} > F^{2}\). Likewise, if \(M^{j*} = 0\) or \(M^{j*} = M{}_{\rm max}\)(\(j = 2\), 3), the conclusion is invalid.

(iv) Under the same conditions, we have \({{\Pi_{r}^{3} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{\Pi_{r}^{3} } {\Pi_{r}^{0} }}} \right. \kern-0pt} {\Pi_{r}^{0} }} > {{\Pi_{s}^{3} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{\Pi_{s}^{3} } {\Pi_{s}^{0} }}} \right. \kern-0pt} {\Pi_{s}^{0} }}\) when \(M^{3*} > 0\). There are two major reasons can explain the phenomenon. First, the supplier burdens an additional capital opportunity cost, i.e., \(CKe^{aM} I_{s} M\). Second, the supplier burdens the default risk of trade credit from the retailer reduces his or her expected net revenue. Moreover, as shown in Table 1, we find that if \(0 < M^{3*} < M_{\rm max}\), \({{\Pi_{r}^{3} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{\Pi_{r}^{3} } {\Pi_{r}^{0} }}} \right. \kern-0pt} {\Pi_{r}^{0} }}\), \({{\Pi_{s}^{3} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{\Pi_{s}^{3} } {\Pi_{s}^{0} }}} \right. \kern-0pt} {\Pi_{s}^{0} }}\) and \({{\Pi_{sc}^{3} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{\Pi_{sc}^{3} } {\Pi_{sc}^{0} }}} \right. \kern-0pt} {\Pi_{sc}^{0} }}\) also increase as a, \(A\) and \(W\) increase, and decrease as \(b\), \(C\), \(S_{s}\), \(h_{s}\) and \(I_{s}\) increase. Additionally, \({{\Pi_{r}^{3} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{\Pi_{r}^{3} } {\Pi_{r}^{0} }}} \right. \kern-0pt} {\Pi_{r}^{0} }}\), \({{\Pi_{s}^{3} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{\Pi_{s}^{3} } {\Pi_{s}^{0} }}} \right. \kern-0pt} {\Pi_{s}^{0} }}\) and \({{\Pi_{sc}^{3} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{\Pi_{sc}^{3} } {\Pi_{sc}^{0} }}} \right. \kern-0pt} {\Pi_{sc}^{0} }}\) is highly sensitive to a, \(W\), \(b\) and \(C\), moderately sensitive to \(I_{s}\), and has a low sensitive or insensitive to \(S_{s}\), \(A\) and \(h_{s}\).

(v) In most situations, \(\Pi_{sc}^{3} > \Pi_{sc}^{1}\), \(\Pi_{sc}^{2} > \Pi_{sc}^{1}\), i.e., the total profits of supply chain under the two games are better than the results under centralized decision, only if the optimal trade credit period should not be too short. That is to say, the supply chain’s total profits with longer trade credit period under the two games are both greater than the profit of centralized decision. It indicates that trade credit can be used as coordination parameter.

Conclusions

How to determinate an optimal trade credit period? This question is gaining more and more attention from researchers. In this paper, we discuss about two retailer–supplier uncooperative replenishment models with default risk under trade credit policy, i.e., a Nash equilibrium model and a supplier-Stackelberg model.

Generally, the main trait of this paper compared to most existing uncooperative inventory model is that the developed model includes the following aspects: (i) Nash equilibrium game and supplier-Stackelberg game; (ii) the results of decentralized decision and centralized decision without trade credit as comparison benchmarks; (iii) the retailer’s capital opportunity cost equal to its opportunity gain; (iv) trade credit period is a decision variable; (v) the demand and default risk both are exponential functions of trade credit period; (vi) lot-for-lot policy; and (vii) the production rate is finite but the replenishment is instantaneous. The major contribution of the paper is that we fully compare between the results of decentralized and centralized decision without trade credit, Nash equilibrium and a supplier-Stackelberg model with trade credit in detail, and obtain some interesting managerial insights and practical implications.

In this paper, we first derive the existence and uniqueness conditions of the optimal solutions for the retailer and the supplier under non-collaborative replenishment policies, i.e., Nash equilibrium game and supplier-Stackelberg game. Moreover, we develop a set of theorems and corollaries to determine the optimal solution and obtain some managerial insights. For instance, a higher value of \(a\), \(W\), \(A\) and a lower value of \(b\), \(C\), \(S_{s}\), \(h_{s}\), \(I_{s}\) cause a higher value of \(M^{{2\bar{*}}}\) and \(M^{{3\bar{*}}}\). Finally, we provide an example and sensitivity analysis to illustrate the proposed strategy. Sensitivity analysis reveals that the total profits of supply chain under the two games are better than the results under centralized decision when the optimal trade credit period isn’t too short, also suggests that the size of \(M^{j*}\), \(F^{j}\), \(D^{j}\), \(\Pi_{r}^{j}\), and \(\Pi_{s}^{j}\) (\(j = 2,3\)) have a strong relationship with a, \(W\), \(b\) and \(C\). In addition, we present other main managerial insights.

The previous results have some practical implications. On the one hand, a supplier may offer a retailer trade credit to expand the demand under certain conditions, especially for the growth phase or launch phase of a product life cycle, even to avoid lasting price competition from competitors. We usually observe that sales volume increases with trade credit period, but production cost decreases with time during the two stages of product life cycle. On the other hand, trade credit is an important financing tool for retailers, especially, the small and micro or starting-up retailer having lack of capital. However, for trade credit of default risk from retailers, the supplier should carefully select good retailers. Moreover, the retailer should set up a fine credit record in the markets, or a long-term relationship with the supplier.

For further research, we may extend the model to allow for other demand functions, such as quadratic trade credit period demand, varying demand both with trade credit period and time, etc. In addition, we may further consider deteriorating items, shortages, environmental impact, warehouse capacity constraint and single supplier/multi-retailer non-coordination and others. Therefore, the effects of all of these additional scenarios may be incorporated in future research.

References

  • Abad PL, Jaggi CK (2003) A joint approach for setting unit price and the length of the credit period for a seller when end demand is price sensitive. Int J Prod Econ 83(2):115–122

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aggarwal SP, Jaggi CK (1995) Ordering policies of deteriorating items under permissible delay in payments. J Oper Res Soc 46(5):658–662

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Andriolo A, Battini D, Grubbström RW, Persona A, Sgarbossa F (2014) A century of evolution from Harris׳ s basic lot size model: survey and research agenda. Int J Prod Econ 155:16–38

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Azzi A, Battini D, Faccio M, Persona A, Sgarbossa F (2014) Inventory holding costs measurement: a multi-case study. Int J Log Manag 25(1):109–132

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Battini D, Persona A, Sgarbossa F (2014) A sustainable EOQ model: theoretical formulation and applications. Int J Prod Econ 149:145–153

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chan CK, Lee YCE, Goyal SK (2010) A delayed payment method in co-ordinating a single-vendor multi-buyer supply chain. Int J Prod Econ 127(1):95–102

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chang HJ, Dye CY (2001) An inventory model for deteriorating items with partial backlogging and permissible delay in payments. Int J Syst Sci 32(3):345–352

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Chang CT, Teng JT, Goyal SK (2008) Inventory lot-size models under trade credits: a review. Asia Pac J Oper Res 25(1):89–112

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Chen LH, Kang FS (2007) Integrated vendor–buyer cooperative inventory models with variant permissible delay in payments. Eur J Oper Res 183(1):658–673

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Chen SC, Teng JT (2014) Retailer’s optimal ordering policy for deteriorating items with maximum lifetime under supplier’s trade credit financing. Appl Math Model 38(15):4049–4061

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Chen SC, Teng JT (2015) Inventory and credit decisions for time-varying deteriorating items with up-stream and down-stream trade credit financing by discounted cash flow analysis. Eur J Oper Res 243(2):566–575

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Chern MS, Pan QH, Teng JT, Chan YL, Chen SC (2013) Stackelberg solution in a vendor-buyer supply chain model with permissible delay in payments. Int J Prod Econ 144(1):397–404

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chern MS, Chan YL, Teng JT, Goyal SK (2014) Nash equilibrium solution in a vendor–buyer supply chain model with permissible delay in payments. Comput Ind Eng 70(1):116–123

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chu P, Chung KJ, Lan SP (1998) Economic order quantity of deteriorating items under permissible delay in payments. Comput Oper Res 25(10):817–824

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Chung KJ (2013) The EOQ model with defective items and partially permissible delay in payments linked to order quantity derived analytically in the supply chain management. Appl Math Model 37(1):2317–2326

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Dye CY, Yang CT (2015) Sustainable trade credit and replenishment decisions with credit-linked demand under carbon emission constraints. Eur J Oper Res 244(1):187–200

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Giri BC, Maiti T (2013) Supply chain model with price-and trade credit-sensitive demand under two-level permissible delay in payments. Int J Syst Sci 44(5):937–948

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Glock CH, Kim T (2015) The effect of forward integration on a single-vendor–multi-retailer supply chain under retailer competition. Int J Prod Econ 164:179–192

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glock CH, Grosse EH, Ries JM (2014) The lot sizing problem: a tertiary study. Int J Prod Econ 155:39–51

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goyal SK (1985) Economic order quantity under conditions of permissible delay in payments. J Oper Res Soc 36(4):335–338

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Ho CH (2011) The optimal integrated inventory policy with price-and-credit-linked demand under two-level trade credit. Comput Ind Eng 60(1):117–126

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hsu JT, Hsu LF (2013) An integrated vendor–buyer cooperative inventory model in an imperfect production process with shortage backordering. Int J Adv Manuf Technol 65(1–4):493–505

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huang YF (2003) Optimal retailer’s ordering policies in the EOQ model under trade credit financing. J Oper Res Soc 54(9):1011–1015

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Huang CK, Tsai DM, Wu JC, Chung KJ (2010) An integrated vendor–buyer inventory model with order-processing cost reduction and permissible delay in payments. Eur J Oper Res 202(2):473–478

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Jaber MY, Osman IH (2006) Coordinating a two-level supply chain with delay in payments and profit sharing. Comput Ind Eng 50(4):385–400

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jaggi CK, Goyal SK, Goel SK (2008) Retailer’s optimal replenishment decisions with credit-linked demand under permissible delay in payments. Eur J Oper Res 190(1):130–135

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Jain D, Aggarwal KK (2012) The effect of inflation-induced demand and trade credit on ordering policy of exponentially deteriorating and imperfect quality items. Int Trans Oper Res 19(6):863–889

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Jeuland AP, Shugan SM (1983) Managing channel profits. Mark Sci 2(3):239–272

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Khouja M, Mehrez A (1996) Optimal inventory policy under different supplier credit policies. J Manuf Syst 15(5):334–339

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kim J, Hwang H, Shinn S (1995) An optimal credit policy to increase supplier’s profits with price-dependent demand functions. Prod Plan Control 6(1):45–50

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krichen S, Laabidi A, Abdelaziz FB (2011) Single supplier multiple cooperative retailers inventory model with quantity discount and permissible delay in payments. Comput Ind Eng 60(1):164–172

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lou KR, Wang WC (2012) Optimal trade credit and order quantity when trade credit impacts on both demand rate and default risk. J Oper Res Soc 64(10):1551–1556

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marchi B, Ries JM, Zanoni S, Glock CH (2016) A joint economic lot size model with financial collaboration and uncertain investment opportunity. Int J Prod Econ 176:170–182

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Molamohamadi Z, Ismail N, Leman Z, Zulkifli N (2014) Reviewing the literature of inventory models under trade credit contact. Discrete Dyn Nat Soc 59(9):1342–1349

    Google Scholar 

  • Ouyang LY, Chuang CJ, Ho CH, Wu CW (2014) An integrated inventory model with quality improvement and two-part credit policy. TOP 22(3):1042–1061

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Sarmah SP, Acharya D, Goyal SK (2008) Coordination of a single-manufacturer/multi-buyer supply chain with credit option. Int J Prod Econ 111(2):676–685

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Seifert D, Seifert RW, Protopappa-Sieke M (2013) A review of trade credit literature: opportunities for research in operations. Eur J Oper Res 231(2):245–256

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shah NH, Cárdenas-Barrón LE (2015) Retailer’s decision for ordering and credit policies for deteriorating items when a supplier offers order-linked credit period or cash discount. Appl Math Comput 259(15):569–578

    MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Teng JT (2002) On the economic order quantity under conditions of permissible delay in payments. J Oper Res Soc 53(8):915–918

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Teng JT, Chang CT (2009) Optimal manufacturer’s replenishment policies in the EPQ model under two levels of trade credit policy. Eur J Oper Res 195(2):358–363

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Teng JT, Lou KR (2012) Seller’s optimal credit period and replenishment time in a supply chain with up-stream and down-stream trade credits. J Glob Optim 53(3):417–430

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Teng JT, Chang CT, Chern MS (2012a) Vendor-buyer inventory models with trade credit financing under both non-cooperative and integrated environments. Int J Syst Sci 43(11):2050–2061

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Teng JT, Min J, Pan QH (2012b) Economic order quantity model with trade credit financing for non-decreasing demand. OMEGA 40(3):328–335

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Teng JT, Lou KR, Wang L (2014) Optimal trade credit and lot size policies in economic production quantity models with learning curve production costs. Int J Prod Econ 155:318–323

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wang WC, Teng JT, Lou KR (2014) Seller’s optimal credit period and cycle time in a supply chain for deteriorating items with maximum lifetime. Eur J Oper Res 232(2):315–321

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Wu J, Ouyang LY, Cárdenas-Barrón LE, Goyal SK (2014) Optimal credit period and lot size for deteriorating items with expiration dates under two-level trade credit financing. Eur J Oper Res 237(3):898– 908

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Wu CF, Zhao QH (2014a) Supplier-retailer inventory coordination with credit term for inventory-dependent and linear-trend demand. Int Trans Oper Res 21(5):797–818

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Wu CF, Zhao QH (2014b) Supplier–buyer deterministic inventory coordination with trade credit and shelf-life constraint. Int J Syst Sci Oper Logist 1(1):36–46

    Google Scholar 

  • Wu CF, Zhao QH (2015a) An inventory model for deteriorating items with inventory-dependent and linear trend demand under trade credit. Sci Iran 22(6):2258–2570

    Google Scholar 

  • Wu CF, Zhao QH (2015b) An uncooperative ordering policy with time-varying price and learning curve for time-varying demand under trade credit. Working paper. Qingdao University of Science & Technology, China

  • Yang PC, Wee HM (2006) A collaborative inventory system with permissible delay in payment for deteriorating items. Math Comput Model 43(3):209–221

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Zhou YW, Zhou D (2013) Determination of the optimal trade credit policy: a supplier-Stackelberg model. J Oper Res Soc 64(7):1030–1048

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhou YW, Zhong YW, Li JC (2012) An uncooperative order model for items with trade credit, inventory-dependent demand and limited displayed-shelf space. Eur J Oper Res 223(1):76–85

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Zhou YW, Zhong YG, Wahab MIM (2013) How to make the replenishment and payment strategy under flexible two-part trade credit. Comput Oper Res 40(5):1328–1338

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

Download references

Authors’ contributions

CFW drafted the manuscript and analyzed the data. QHZ designed the study. All authors read and approved the final manuscript.

Acknowledgements

This work is supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China (71471006, 91224007), Ministry of education of Humanities and Social Science Youth Fund Project (16YJC630135), Shandong Province Soft Science Research Plan Project (2014RKB01289).

Competing interests

The authors declare that they have no competing interests.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Chengfeng Wu.

Rights and permissions

Open Access This article is distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons license, and indicate if changes were made.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Wu, C., Zhao, Q. Two retailer–supplier supply chain models with default risk under trade credit policy. SpringerPlus 5, 1728 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1186/s40064-016-3346-3

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1186/s40064-016-3346-3

Keywords