Skip to main content

Extended inclusive fitness theory: synergy and assortment drives the evolutionary dynamics in biology and economics

Abstract

W.D. Hamilton’s Inclusive Fitness Theory explains the conditions that favor the emergence and maintenance of social cooperation. Today we know that these include direct and indirect benefits an agent obtains by its actions, and through interactions with kin and with genetically unrelated individuals. That is, in addition to kin-selection, assortation or homophily, and social synergies drive the evolution of cooperation. An Extended Inclusive Fitness Theory (EIFT) synthesizes the natural selection forces acting on biological evolution and on human economic interactions by assuming that natural selection driven by inclusive fitness produces agents with utility functions that exploit assortation and synergistic opportunities. This formulation allows to estimate sustainable cost/benefit threshold ratios of cooperation among organisms and/or economic agents, using existent analytical tools, illuminating our understanding of the dynamic nature of society, the evolution of cooperation among kin and non-kin, inter-specific cooperation, co-evolution, symbioses, division of labor and social synergies. EIFT helps to promote an interdisciplinary cross fertilization of the understanding of synergy by, for example, allowing to describe the role for division of labor in the emergence of social synergies, providing an integrated framework for the study of both, biological evolution of social behavior and economic market dynamics. Another example is a bio-economic understanding of the motivations of terrorists, which identifies different forms of terrorism.

Background

The present paper does not pretend to present novel facts nor brand new theory. It aims at producing a synthesis of known facts that open novel windows that allow for fresh views on established knowledge, favoring the flux of ideas between areas of science that have developed quite independently from each other. New multidisciplinary ways to look at old facts broaden our understanding of nature by helping us rethink established dogma in search of Consilience (Wilson 1999). Here I present a synthesis of a life long effort in building such an interdisciplinary window.

The theory of evolution, formulated by Darwin and Wallace some time ago, was built on the insight that heredity, natural selection, and variability interacted to produce biological evolution. The breakthrough in thinking was not the discovery of natural selection, or of heredity, or diversity. All these features were described in detail by Alexander von Humboldt, much cited by Darwin, and who lived a generation before Darwin and Wallace (Humboldt died the year Darwin published the Origin of Species). Humboldt had a working knowledge of selection and of the importance of the survival of the strongest, of heredity and the logic of domestication of plants and animals by selective breeding, and was aware about diversity, describing detailed variations between species and among species (Humboldt 1807). The important contribution by Wallace and Darwin was the insight that evolution emerged from the synergistic interaction of these three features, and that this evolutionary dynamics could explain the emergence of species (Top right cycle in Fig. 1). That is, the continuous interaction between heredity, variations produced by mutations and the environment, and natural selection, produce the evolutionary dynamics that allows species to adapt to their environments and eventually diverge in their evolutionary path producing new species. That is, natural selection operates through the differential reproduction of individuals, measured as fitness. Higher levels of fitness are achieved by higher rates of reproduction, which in turn may be enhanced by higher survival probabilities. This theory, however, had difficulties in explaining many mating displays using exceptionally bright colors, ornate plumage and conspicuous forms among living creatures, which attract predators and thus decreased the odds of individual survival. To overcome this limitation, Darwin introduced the concept of sexual selection to complement that of individual selection to explain biological evolution (Bottom right cycle in Fig. 1). Darwin open two conceptually different ways at looking at fitness: individual survival that favors the strongest and most able individual, and sexual selection that favors the most prolific in mates and descendants. Either selecting forces might work synchronously, or they might diverge. Although both, survival and reproduction, are parts of the individual’s fitness, theory that looks separately at each of the two processes help us in gaining a deeper understanding of evolution.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Schematic representation of selected aspects or components of the network of relationships responsible for the dynamics of natural Selection driving biological evolution. Individual Selection (i) represents natural selection acting on the individual; Sexual Selection (s) that acts on mate selection strategies and intra-sex competition; and Inclusive Fitness (o) cycles represents the coevolutionary effect on selection of the action of other organisms. Variation represents genetic mutations and phenotypic variations, Reproduction represents the reproductive and life history strategies of individuals, and Mating stands for sexual reproduction. Organisms suffer evolution through Individual Selection (bold arrows), which in turn is affected by at least two other cycles: Sexual Selection and Inclusive Fitness. Evolution among asexuals differs from this description (Jaffe 1996), as no mating’s occurrs

Soon after Darwin, important advances in our understanding about how evolution proceeds emerged. Development of population genetics, mainly between 1918 and 1932, and the expansion of Mendelian genetics were incorporated together with a more detailed theory of natural selection and gradual evolution into a modern evolutionary synthesis. This modern synthesis, produced between 1936 and 1947, reflects the consensus that is still valid today (Haldane 1932; Huxley 1942; Fisher 1958; Dobzhansky 1970; Mayr 1963; and others). The next important advance was a better understanding of cooperation and the emergence of societies that was not explained satisfactorily by Darwin (1859) and Wallace (1870) nor the just mentioned synthesis (Wilson 2000). Cooperation is important in a number of settings, including, behavioral interactions, biological evolution, sociobiology, cultural dynamics, and collective intelligence; yet the features allowing it succeed are not well known and are still discussed today (Grafen and Archetti 2008; Hadzibeganovic et al. 2014; Hofbauer and Sigmund 2003; Jaffe 2004a; Nowak and May 1993; Seinen and Schram 2006; Skyrms et al. 2014; Zimmerman et al. 2000). Inclusive Fitness Theory (IFT) as originally stated by Hamilton (1963, 1964), has been the most successful theory so far to provide explanations for the evolution of cooperation. Hamilton grasped that the effect of other individuals (con-specifics or not) affect the odds of survival of an individual. Specially among social species, the action of others could affect the fitness of an individual, so as to form a web of relations that affect the fitness of the participating organisms (The top left cycle in Fig. 1 represents just one cell of such a network).

In 1963 Hamilton published his first paper about inclusive fitness. The root of the argument was the idea of “a multi-factorial model of inheritance, which is doubtless more realistic, (… where) fitness is reckoned in terms of ‘inclusive’ genotype-reproduction”. He specifically wrote: “As a simple but admittedly crude model we may imagine a pair of genes g and G such that G tends to cause some kind of altruistic behavior while g is null. Despite the principle of ‘survival of the fittest’ the ultimate criterion which determines whether G will spread is not whether the behavior is to the benefit of the beaver but whether it is to the benefit of the gene G; and this will be the case if the average net result of the behavior is to add to the gene-pool a handful of genes containing G in higher concentration than does the gene-pool itself”. This idea was then molded, as a response to the rejection of this paper by the journal Nature (see below), to focus more on kin-selection (Hamilton 1964) leading to the formulation of IFT as an expression quantifying the fitness costs of a cooperative interaction as c < b. r; where “c” is the fitness cost to the donor in a cooperative act, “b” the benefit to the receiver, and “r” as the probability that an allele in one individual will also be present in a second individual via common descent. This simple formula, centered on “c < b”, is a consequence of the law for the conservation of energy, or first law of thermodynamics, as applied to biology: in the long term, survival of organisms requires that its total energy expenditure must be equal or lower than its total income. In order for fitness to be positive, positive survival rates are required. Hamilton’s proposition was to treat “b” as a quantity modulated by “r”. The focus of IFT on kin was aided by historical events. Soon after rejecting Hamilton’s original paper on IFT submitted to Nature (Segerstrale 2013, and personal communication by W. Hamilton and by J. Maynard Smith), Maynard Smith (Maynard-Smith 1964) introduced the Kin Selection Theory (KST) to explain the phenomena Hamilton described as IFT. Thus, Hamilton emphasize kin-selection narratives in his 1964 papers to show that IFT included it. Even in the paper rejected by Nature, which was published in some form in The America Naturalist in 1963, he had to add to the aforementioned paragraph on inclusive fitness “With altruism this will happen only if the affected individual is a relative of the altruist, therefore having an increased chance of carrying the gene, and if the advantage conferred is large enough compared to the personal disadvantage to offset the regression, or ‘dilution,’ of the altruist’s genotype in the relative in question”. Clearly, Hamilton was a strong supporter of Price () version of IFT which puts emphasis to the first part of this expression (only access to the rejected paper by Nature will solve this dispute, which hopefully will happen soon). This historical circumstance has obscured the relevance of IFT until today and favored that of KST, which is more intuitive and easier to understand. Several other narratives of the evolution of the concept of inclusive fitness exist, that diverge from the one presented here (Hölldobler and Wilson 2009; Nowak et al. 2010; Bourke 2011; Birch and Okasha 2015 for example).

Independent of history, the difference between KST and IFT is that the former only considers the genetic relationship between cooperating individuals as relevant for calculating fitness, whereas the later accepts that other factors are also relevant. KST simplifies IFT by assuming that “r” in the formula “c < b. r”, represents “only” the genetic relatedness between donor and receiver. This simplification, though, has become very popular. So much so that Google Scholar in April 2015 retrieved about 1.4 more papers using the term “kin selection” compared to “inclusive fitness”. Many scholars today still do not distinguishable between both concepts. (see Gardner et al. 2011; Allen et al. 2013; Corning 2013, for example). This confusion between KST and IFT is augmented by histories of IFT that assign Haldane a primary role in it (see for example Hölldobler and Wilson 2009). Yet, relating Haldane’s (1932) casual comments on how expanded parental care may be favored by selection, with a pioneering role in the development of IFT, is equivalent to calling Alexander von Humboldt the grandfather of Darwin’s theory of evolution. Modern evolutionary theory give to the components affecting inclusive fitness that are nor related to kin a much more important role in explaining evolutionary phenomena, including economics, than those considered by KST. The main shortcoming of KST is that it focuses on the actions between genetic relatives as drivers for the evolution of cooperation, whereas IFT also explains cooperative interactions between non-kin.

Substituting IFT with KST was never accepted by Hamilton (Segerstrale 2013 and personal communication), and even Maynard Smith (1983) eventually recognized its distinctiveness. IFT is a much more general theoretical framework than KST, which is a special aspect of the former. The focus on inclusive fitness rather than on kin selection allows for a finer understanding of population genetic dynamics. Inclusive fitness being >0 can be the right criterion for social behavior to be selected, also in models where kin selection is absent, and where assortment is brought about by something other than common descent. Inclusive fitness, in addition to the genetic relatedness between the actors in cooperation, takes into account “the likelihood of sharing genes above random levels due to statistical effects in genetic population dynamics” (Price 1970). This means that the effect of co-variance on selection also determines the degree of assortation that may occur between organisms (Price 1971). IFT is an open theoretical framework, which might conceive as multipliers to “b” any means that increase the frequency of an allele in a population through social interactions, such as mutualism, synergistic cooperation and others (Queller 1985, 1992, 2011). It is not necessary to refer any more to kin-selection. Fletcher and Doebeli (2006) wrote: “The most fundamental explanation for how altruism (defined by local interactions) increases in a population requires that there be assortment in the population such that the benefit from others falls sufficiently often to carriers (and at the same time non-altruists are stuck interacting more with each other). Nonadditivity if present can play a similar role: when collective cooperation yields synergistic benefits (positive non-additivity) altruistic behavior can evolve even in the absence of positive assortment, and when there are diminishing returns for cooperation (negative non-additivity) the evolution of altruism is hindered (Queller 1985; Hauert et al. 2006).”

Independently to the theoretical development just described, robust tools for handling non linear emergent phenomena in mathematical biology, such as numerical simulations, reached the same conclusions, confirming a central role for social synergy in the evolution of cooperation, specially among non-kin groups. That is, agent based computer simulations studying the evolutionary dynamics of inclusive fitness on haploids, diploids, haplo-diploids, asexual and sexual organisms, showed that social cooperation without social synergy is unable to emerge and sustain itself in scenarios for biological evolution (Jaffe 2001) and in scenarios of economic markets (Jaffe 2002a). These simulations, validated by empirical experimentation (Crespi 2001; Chuang et al. 2010; Harcombe 2010), showed that both, biological evolution of social behavior and market dynamics, require social synergy for its working. Social synergy is defined here as the process by which emergent properties arise through social interactions. For example, cooperation in retrieving food by insects allows them to handle food that no single individual would be able to capture and retrieve alone, expanding opportunities to exploit novel niches to groups of cooperating foraging workers. Such type of cooperation seems to explain the evolution of social behavior among bees (Michener 1969) and wasps (Silva and Jaffe 2002). Social synergy is not reduced to an abstract concept as it can be measured quantitatively and empirically in different settings (Jaffe 2010). Cooperation were all interacting individuals benefit are also called Mutualism (Axelrod and Hamilton 1981; Bronstein 1994; Hoeksema and Bruna 2000, for example) and can be viewed as a special kind of social synergy.

EIFT is based on Queller’s version of Hamilton’s rule (Queller 1985), as presented by Fletcher and Doebeli (2006), who formulated “r”, the modulator of “b” as a ratio of covariances (cov) so that: r = cov(GA, P0)/cov(GA, PA) where GA measures the genotype or breeding value in each individual in the population (subscript A for actor), PA the phenotypic value of each actor (e.g. 0 for defection and 1 for cooperation), and P0 is the average phenotype of others interacting with each individual actor (subscript O for others).

This formulation implies that the altruistic genotype represented by GA increases in frequency if those with the genotype on average get more benefit from the behavior of others than they pay in cost for their own behavior. This relationship uses measures of assortment (covariance) between those with this focal genotype and the helping behaviours of others, scaled by the value of these behaviors. Taking the covariance over the whole population ensures that if this inequality holds for the helping genotype, it cannot simultaneously hold for the alternative nonaltruistic genotype. Therefore, when Hamilton’s rule is satisfied, carriers on average have higher direct fitness than the population average (For details see Fletcher and Doebeli 2006).

Here I propose a slightly different formulation that facilitates its application to human economic dynamics. This expanded theory allows to bridge conceptual divides between biological and economic sciences. Recently, Corning and Szathmáry (2015) presented a similar bioconomic evolutionary approach to cooperation giving a preponderant role to synergy in evolution, without using genetic population theory’s “r”. This approach is based on Corning’s Hi Synergism Hypothesis, first presented in his pioneering and extensive book with this name (Corning 1983) sowed the wonderful working of synergy in biology. Corning expanded the synergism hypothesis in several publications (Corning 2007, 2013 for example) provide and extended detailed analysis of synergy in biology and bioeconomics. The Synergism Hypothesis proposes that cooperative effects of various kinds have played a key role in the evolutionary process via Synergistic Selection (a sub-category of natural selection) and focuses on synergy of scale and multi-level and group selection (specially in Corning and Szathmáry 2015). The present analysis, developed completely independent of the one by Corning, complements the analysis presented by Corning and aims to develop tools that allow a more quantitative study of synergy (see Jaffe and Febres 2016 for example).

Expanding inclusive fitness theory

A dynamic narrative that includes both biological and cultural evolution requires three assumptions, definitions or concepts in order to formulate an EIFT.

  1. 1.

    The first is to refer to agents as a concept that includes organisms and social structures. In biology, mating is described as cooperation between two agents to produce offspring; whereas in economics, cooperating agents are productive units, which can be individuals or aggregates such as companies. Cooperation is at the heart of any business and thus the basis of economic dynamics. Using agents as the unit for dynamic studies is getting more common in biology, sociology, ecology and economics as shown by the ever-increasing literature (some examples are: Axelrod 1997; Pepper and Smuts 2000; Bonabeau 2002; Epstein 2006; Tesfatsion and Judd 2006; in addition to the literature cited so far).

  2. 2.

    Another definition that requires modification is reproduction. Reproduction should be viewed as reproduction of information, which includes diffusion and multiplication of information. This information can be of the genetic kind in biology, or, in economy it might mean memes (Dawkins 1989), information attached to productive systems (Hausmann and Hidalgo 2014), or scientific knowledge quantifiable with scientific papers (Jaffe et al. 2013b), etc.

  3. 3.

    The third definition is a synthesis of the concept of evolutionary fitness function with economic utility function (Kenrick et al. 2009). If we assume that natural selection molded behavior of extant organisms, including humans, so that they maximize their capacity for adaptation, then behaviors that aim to optimize the fitness of an individual will take into account the same natural selection forces working in evolution. As evolutionary fitness functions and economic utility functions are the product of the same natural forces, they will have equivalent structures dealing with the same constraints (Jaffe 2009), including those formulated by IFT.

As represented in Fig. 1, the fitness of an individual has at least three aspects or components:

  1. 1.

    The selection acting on the survival capabilities of the individual that relate to its capacity to manage and respond to its environment (i),

  2. 2.

    The abilities to mate and reproduce that can be grouped under sexual selection (s),

  3. 3.

    The inclusive fitness or fitness affected by the presence and actions of other individuals with which it interacts or which it bestows upon others (o).

The total fitness of an individual (f) is a composite function, which includes the fitness conferred by the phenotype of the individual, which in turn depends on its individual survival capabilities (i) and its reproductive success (s). In addition, f depends on the consequences of interactions with others (o), so that: f = f(i, s, o)

The component “o” has at least 3 parts to it. 1. The likelihood that a gene is present in another individual due to genetic relatedness or the kin selection component (k), 2. The probability that a gene is shared due to assortation (a), 3. The probability that a gene will favor the fitness of another due social synergies or economic considerations that emerge from the presence of specific alleles in each individual (e). Therefore: o = f(k, a, e).

Assortation includes the concepts of kin selection, as preference for cooperating with kin is a specific kind of assortation. Thus o = f(a, e). The fitness of the individual f can be summarized as the product of two related networks of relationship: f i or factors affecting individual fitness directly; and f o or factors affecting the individual fitness via the action of others:

$${\text{f}} = f_{i} ({\text{i}},{\text{s}},f_{o} \left( {a,e)} \right)$$

This formulation converges with that supported by Queller (1985, 2011), Fletcher and Doebeli (2006) and others, in that is treats assortation (a) and social synergy or non additive benefits (e) as the most important features determining the evolutionary viability of cooperation. Of all these terms, a and e are the less well understood and will explained below.

Assortation

Assortation refers to the fact that similar organism attract each other. This is described in phrases such as “birds of one feather flock together” and is also refereed to as homophily: love for things similar to oneself; or narcissism: love of oneself. The term assortation was already used by Hamilton (1975) and he helped to show its relevance to IFT motivating George R. Price to develop a mathematically useful formulation (Price 1971). This paper showed that assortative mating can increase the frequency of an allele. This effect was shown to be so fundamental that it also works in mate choice in sexual reproduction (Jaffe 2002b). Complementing these findings, computer simulations showed that without some kind of assortative mating, sexual reproduction is unlikely to emerge among complex diplod organisms (Jaffe 2001).

The working of assortation in favoring the success of cooperative strategies seem to be associated with the possibility of forming globular clusters, as is the case of some network structures (Kuperman and Risau-Gusman 2012). Assortation is favored by tags or a green beard effect (Hamilton 1964), consisting of signals, behaviors or other features that allow agents to discriminate among potential cooperators and regulate the type of agents that will interact cooperatively (Riolo et al. 2001; Kim 2010). A very basic form of cooperation often occurs among sexually reproducing mates. But assortation or homopyly evolves in many other cooperative interactions (Fu et al. 2012). Many behaviors of modern humans, such as the choice of mates and pets, can be explained as a result of assortation. For example humans select mates based on visual perception of their faces (Alvarez and Jaffe 2004), or of their pets (Payne and Jaffe 2005), and friends (Christakis and Fowler 2014) assortatively. In addition, homophily is very common in social settings (Centola et al. 2007; Kossinets and Watts 2009). Assortation or homophily have particular interesting effects on the evolutionary dynamics of cooperation, even beyond what can be explained with IFT. They reduce error thresholds of mutations (Ochoa and Jaffe 2006), and accelerate the speed of evolution (Jaffe 2001), favoring the emergence and maintenance of cooperation (Jaffe 2002b).

Assortation has been studied extensively in assortative mating and assortative cooperation (see review in Jaffe 2002b). Empirical evidence for assortation has been mounting. Here, just few random examples: Evidence among vertebrates include studies showing that chimpanzee friendships are based on homophily in personality (Massen and Koski 2014); the existence of assortative mating in lesser snow geese (Cooke et al. 1976) and in blue tits (Andersson and Andersson 1998); assortation among humans in games of experimental economics (Bowles and Gintis 2005; Hamilton and Taborsky 2005); from anthropological and archaeological studies (Apicella et al. 2012; Durrett and Levin 2005); and of course, from ethology (Alvarez and Jaffe 2004, Payne and Jaffe 2005).

Social synergy

Much work on cooperation has centered on altruism. Indeed, the ultimate sacrifice of ants and bees for the good of their colonies is an impressive feat. But eventually, all sustainable social behaviors involve interactions that are beneficial to all intervening parts (Fletcher and Doebeli 2006). Interactions where all parties gain, the so-called win–win interactions (Fig. 2), are very much known among economist (Lewicki et al. 1985; Dolfsma and Soete 2006; Liu and Huang 2007). One important concept is Social synergy, i.e. non-additive benefits and positive feedback of social behavior that affect individual fitness. Social synergy refers to synergies triggered by social cooperation that increase economic and other benefits to social individuals favoring its evolution (Queller 1992, 2011; Jaffe 2001, 2002a, b, 2010; Taylor 2013). Synergies that emerge from social interactions can be quantified (Jaffe 2010; Bettencourt 2013), and are fundamental in explaining the maintenance of complex societies (Jaffe 2002a).

Fig. 2
figure 2

Effect of different cooperative strategies on the fitness of the actors

Although not ignored, social synergy has been little studied quantitatively among living creatures other than humans (Jaffe 2010). The father of IFT already recognized that several different mechanisms are needed to explain the prevalence of social cooperation among extant species (Hamilton 1996). Studying bees, Michener (1969) demonstrated the existence of several different evolutionary routes leading to sophisticated societies that benefited all or most of its members. To understand these evolutionary dynamics, economic and ecological considerations are more important than genetic ones (Osborn and Jaffe 1997; Silva and Jaffe 2002).

Political economists have studied the economic forces unleashed by human cooperation for many years (Krotopkin 1902 for example). More recently, Social synergy has been mentioned when studying pay off matrices, altruistic punishment, benefits of social life and cooperation The cost/benefit ratio of cooperation might reveal the existence of this synergy. Cost/benefit ratios have been shown to be important for the evolution of cooperation in different settings (Nowak and Sigmund 1998, 2005; Jaffe 2002a, b; Nowak 2006; Baranski et al. 2006; Ohtsuki et al. 2006; Jaffe and Zaballa 2010; Taylor 2013).

In interactions involving exploitation or parasitism, one organisms benefit at the expense of the other, increasing its fitness (bigger dark blue faces) and reducing that of the other (small light blue face). In altruistic interaction the reverse hold. The altruist reduces its fitness and the other increases it. Interactions where altruists punish individuals not complying with social norms, both the altruist and the other reduce their fitness. In synergistic business both actors win, increasing their fitness, not necessarily by the same amount (Jaffe 2014a).

From where does this synergy that produces win–win situation arises? Economics has an answer to this question. Long ago, among others, Aristotle recognized that division of labor enlarges and elicits innate human differences (Aristotle IV BC), which allow the existence of complex society. Adam Smith recognized the existence of a special synergy working in the markets as an “invisible hand”, but neither he nor others focused on the specific mechanisms that allowed its working. Adam Smith (1776) writes in The Wealth of Nations “The greatest improvement in the productive powers of labor, and the greater part of the skill, dexterity, and judgment with which it is anywhere directed or applied, seem to have been the effects of the division of labor… It is the great multiplication of the productions of all the different arts, in consequence of the division of labor, which occasions, in a well governed society, that universal opulence which extends itself to the lowest ranks of the people”. Friedrich Hayek (1949), especially when tackling the “Economic Calculus”, and many others (Becker and Murphy 1994 for example), hint to the emergence of synergistic effect in social interactions due to the existence of differently specialized actors. Division of labor has also been associated with social life in insects and many other animals (Wilson 2000) and is correlated with the degree of order in ant societies (Jaffe and Hebling-Beraldo 1993; Jaffe and Fonck 1994). Thus, a very important source of social synergies in the economic dynamics of markets and in biological cooperation is the division of labor. The force behind Adam-Smith’s invisible hand of the market that triggers the complex market dynamics intuitively described by Hayek, is social synergy as described here. This can be evidenced using computer simulations (Jaffe 2015) and robot swarms (Ferrante et al. 2015). It is the specialization of labor that allows complementary interactions to produce ever-stronger synergies that confer non-linear economic advantages to societies that allow and foment individual liberty and division of labor (Jaffe 2014a).

Not all social synergies arise from division of labor. Many other mechanisms are possible. Economies of scale, for example, also allow the individual to achieve higher fitness or economic gains among humans and other animals (Hamilton 1971; Jaffe 2010; Bettencourt 2013). Social intelligence can also be viewed as an emergent phenomenon (Woolley et al. 2010). Again, economic science has explored these issues much more and/or differently than biology.

Among economists, the existence of non-linear dynamics in wealth accumulation has been recognized long ago. Marx (1867) for example, when he described the surplus value and attempted to balance wealth across a society, recognized that more than simple additive arithmetic’s was required. More sophisticated thermodynamic approaches to study non-linear dynamics in economics were initiated by Georgescu-Roegen (1970) and developed further by many others (see Beinhocker 2006 for example) which eventually lead to a systematic use of the concept synergy in economics. Underlying the concept pf social synergy in economics is the fact that some actions and the exploitation of some resources is only possible after a certain threshold size of social aggregates has been reached, producing a non-linear or emergent effect on wealth aggregation.

Examples of synergy used to simulate social evolution in biology can easily be applied to human economics. The example of two wasp mothers that attend their brood communally, each one investing 50 % of their time in brood care, achieving to protect their brood 100 % of the time, reducing the odds of losing their brood to zero with the same cost to parents (Jaffe 2001), can be expanded to human societies and institutions in charge of communal security (Jaffe and Zabala 2010).

A simple example of a synergistic view of the relationship between increased utility and increased wealth is that if a wealthy donor gives a poor recipient a blanket, the recipient will get a much higher utility from the blanket than the donor, but there is no net increase in wealth. But if the object donated is a sewing machine, which is used in the rich donor’s house as decoration, but the poor receiver uses it to produce blankets to sell, then there is a net increase in wealth. The first case illustrates a synergistic increase in utility, the second type one of wealth. (Libb Thims, personal communication).

The more we look at synergy in economics and business management, there more we find meaningful examples. Examples include: the impact of acquisitions on merging and rival firms (Dopfer 1991; Chatterjee 1986), economic development (Evans 1996; Ostrom 1996), mergers and acquisitions (Bradley et al. 1983; Eun et al. 1996; Larsson and Finkelstein 1999), and evidence that certain type of competition over personal resources can favor contribution to shared resources in human groups (Barker et al. 2013).

From biological evolution to economic dynamics

How relevant is EIFT for our understanding of evolution? Cooperation among non-kin is as or more important that between kin. For example, symbioses are far more important in biological evolution than hitherto recognized (Kiers and West 2015; Corning and Szathmáry 2015). Theoretical evolutionary theory needs to digest this fact. In addition, recent reviews provide ample theoretical and empirical evidence justifying the extensions to IFT. For example, Van Cleve and Akcay (2014) showed that the interaction between behavioral responses (reciprocity), genetic relatedness, and synergy interact are fundamental in understanding the richness of social behavior across taxa. The review by Bourke (2014) on “comparative phylogenetic analyses show that cooperative breeding and eusociality are promoted by (i) high relatedness and monogamy and, potentially, by (ii) life-history factors facilitating family structure and high benefits of helping and (iii) ecological factors generating low costs of social behavior”. The last factor is of course the mirror image of social synergy: Environments provide selection pressure to which organisms evolving cooperative strategies producing social synergy has to adapt. Many unequivocal examples of social synergy as a factor in determining the evolutionary success of social behavior have been reported. The best-known example is probably the evolutionary history of social behavior among bees (Michener 1969). In the case in wasps, Hamilton’s preferred species, social behavior generates indirect benefits by enhancing the productivity or survivorship of non-kin more often than that of kin (Strassmann et al. 1991; Itô 1993; Gadagkar and Gadagkar 2009; Jaffe and da Silva 2002, for example).

Biologists are not the only ones interested in social evolution. The features that influence the dynamics of cooperation have been studied using different theoretical frameworks with different specific assumptions. The theoretical framework of studies of social dynamics by biologists, sociologists, economists, physicists, mathematicians, game theorists, computer scientists, and others, differ in the concepts they use despite the fact that all are studying the same basic phenomena, making interdisciplinary communication of this issues difficult. However, all these disciplines have used applications of game theory, and specifically the Prisoner’s Dilemma, to pursue their quest for answers in their fields. Thus, a common language bridging the concepts between these disciplines seems possible.

An important difference between biology and economy is that biology focuses on genetic evolution whereas economy studies cultural processes. This difference is much less important tan the homologies in dynamic processes. For example, Manfred Eigen (1971) insists that Darwinian evolution is not merely the organizing principle of biology but a law of physics that should be responsible for many phenomena in nature. Genetic evolution is based on vertical transmission of information, from parents to offspring, whereas cultural transmission includes in addition to the vertical kind a horizontal transmission of information. The overall evolutionary dynamics of both processes, however indistinguishably (Jaffe and Cipriani 2007). Both processes produce a continuous dynamics that may induce divergence or specialization (Jaffe et al. 2014).

The evolutionary dynamics in biology is centered on genes and organisms, whereas the economic dynamics is centered on business, enterprises and companies. In biology, mating or cooperation between the sexes is fundamental for the survival of the population; whereas in economy it is cooperation among different type of laborers or companies that allows production of wealth. In both cases, the dynamics driving information, innovation and social synergy is similar. EIFT formulas the equation: c < r. b using r = f(a, e) or a function of the probability of the individual to posses a gene that confers it advantages in social interactions with others and the social synergy triggered by this interaction. In the case where the socially advantageous gene is shared between interacting organisms, we speak of assortation. If f(a, e) has evolved by natural selection, economic utility functions are expected to include these same factors. Any comprehensive utility function in economics then has to include besides direct benefit/cost considerations, benefits to kin and group members, to individuals which might reciprocate positively in the future, and any entity that might synergize the individual actions. That is the utility function (u), analogously to the fitness function defined above, has to have at least three different components: u = f(i, a, e). To express it in a way familiar to economists, physicists and mathematician we can write the same formula as:

$$\upsilon = \upphi (\upiota ,\upalpha ,\upvarepsilon )$$

implying that any general utility function in economics (υ) has to take into account the benefits accrued to the agents directly (ι), through interactions with others (α) and through synergies triggered by its behavior (ε).

The bioeconomic insight of EIFT is that the biological fitness function and the economic utility function have the same form, as both are the product of natural selection. The formulation proposed here allows to apply the analytical tools developed by Queller (1985, 1992, 2011) for biological evolution to economics.

Benefits of an extended inclusive fitness theory?

The challenge of EIFT is to explain in more detail how biological and economic systems produce synergies by favoring specialization and division of labor, conferring the individuals in a cooperative society with fitness benefits that are much higher compared to a solitary life (see Jaffe 2015 for example). More experimental approaches in economics are required to address these issues (see Tollefson 2015 for example).

EIFT considers that factors other than genetic relatedness affect the cost benefit balance of cooperation and that fitness functions and utility function have to consider the direct effects on the individual as well as indirect benefits an individual achieves through assortation and synergistic interactions. These factors have been studied with different emphasis by biologist and economist. The most important factor often overlooked so far is probably the social synergy that emerges from cooperative interactions, such as synchronized division of labor. An important conclusion from empirical studies in economics, that try to assess the effect of social synergy or economic benefits that derive from social life, is that synergy is probably the most important driver in the evolution of cooperation, and that assortation or genetic relatedness are neither necessary nor sufficient for the emergence of cooperative phenomena (see also Corning 2013). The same conclusion is reached when exploring the dynamics of cooperation in the repeated prisoners dilemma game (Montoreano and Jaffe 2013). Here social synergy is more important than assortation, which in turn is more important than kin selection, in fomenting cooperation. This suggests that an expanded version of IFT is required for a better understanding of the dynamics. Focusing only on kin selection is not enough. An insight into the economics of the cooperation is fundamental in understanding it. However, little quantitative empirical research on social synergy has been produced in biology (but see Osborn and Jaffe 1997; Jaffe 2010; Smith et al. 2010), though it is recognized as of primary importance in the economics and business literature. The latest reviews of the empirical literature in biology, confirm that a more economic view explains the descriptions of societies found in nature better (Van Cleve and Akcay 2014; Bourke 2014). Even on co-evolution, the review by Ivens (2014) shows a pattern among farming mutualism of ants and their domesticated species that seems to produce stability of these successful mutualisms: The component of inclusive fitness in the evolutionary dynamics (Fig. 1) dwarfs the sexual selection component. Most of these mutalisms are characterized by reduced symbiont dispersal and diversity (often in association with asexual reproduction and vertical transmission), promoted by specific ant behaviors of the ants, such as creation of protective environments. Coevolution, viewed in this new light (see Dawkins and Krebs 1979; Jaffe and Osborn 2004; Zaman et al. 2014, for example), can easily explain many symbioses. Even extravagant proposals such as the one stating that host-microbe interactions influence brain evolution and development in mammals (Stilling et al. 2014), can now be explained. An EIFT makes it unnecessary to treat symbioses and social cooperation as different phenomena as done by Corning (2013), as both are considered in o = f(a, e).

The central insight from recent empirical studies is that economic factors and assortation in its different forms determine social behavior. Social behavior cannot be understood without taking account of all of them. A synergistic interchange of theoretical knowledge between economics and biology looks promising for a novel attempted to deepen our understanding of social dynamics and should help to bridge the gaps in studies of evolution of social cooperation between economist, physicists, biologists, and others, providing for a common language in the quantitative assessment of the importance of specific features that aid social evolution.

A theory that helps us to look for the relevant features in the evolution of social behavior, dynamics of cooperation and evolution of society might be useful. That is, more important than kin relationships are assortation and social synergy for understating social cooperation. Assortation is important in a number of fundamental instances of human cooperation (Jaffe 2002b, 2008; Weisel and Shalvi 2015) and may emerge in many other circumstances if we look for it. The most relevant potential contribution of this theory is that it might allow social science to profit from both economics and biology. It might help develop complexity sciences aiming to improve our understanding of social synergies unleashed by cooperation are of the fundamental forces driving the evolution of societies. These phenomena should be empirically observable. Three examples might help convince the reader about the empirical usefulness of this theory.

Many butterflies have associations with ants. They can either be mutualistic, exploitative or parasitic. Quantitative phylogenetic analysis revealed a large prevalence of cooperation over competition in the symbiotic relationship (Osborn and Jaffe 1997). As no possibility of genetic flow between ants and butterflies exist, there is no doubt here that social synergy is the driving force for cooperation. An impressive large number of symbioses are known to exist (Corning 1983, 2013). This unified treatment of social synergy can be expanded to address the spontaneous commerce and cooperation networks that arise from the working of competitive advantages between nations (Porter 2011) and firms (Grant 1991) in economics, as originally conceived by Ricardo (1891).

Empirical evidence shows that different forms of division of productive activities in an economy accounts for differences in its capacity to produce and accumulate wealth (Hausmann and Hidalgo 2014). This is linked to division of intellectual labor (Jaffe et al. 2010) in contemporary human society. For example, the division of labor in academic research accounts better for differences in relative economic success among nations than any other variable studied so far (Jaffe et al. 2013a, b). These examples show that arrangements that affect social synergies, such as division of labor, are the key to understand contemporary economic development, including the working of finance (Jaffe and Levy-Carciente 2004). An EIFT stimulates the exchange of analytical tools between economists and biologists for a novel view of the working of division of labor (Jaffe 2014b, for example).

From a biological point of view, division of labor in ants is related to increased economic gains of social behavior (Jaffe and Hebling-Beraldo 1993) and at the same time, more sophisticated social behavior is related to a decreased individual complexity (Jaffe and Perez 1989). This is an example of social synergy driving social evolution at the expense of individual selection, easily explainable with the EIFT. In economics, we accept that societies confer energetic benefits to all individuals involved in both ants and humans (Jaffe 2010; Bettencourt 2013). Thus cities allow synergies to emerge that provide non-linear benefits to society (Haken and Portugali 2003; Florida 2005). This synergies are practically everywhere (Corning 1983) and can even be detected in basic physical architectural arrangements (Fuller 1975) and therefore might be present in many as yet unsubscribed situations (Haken 1973). An EIFT might be better able to develop analytical tools to understand how and why synergies emerge from division of labor (Jaffe 2014a).

The study of the interactions between synergy and violence has been fruitful in bioeconomics (Corning 2007), so might EIFT. Inclusive fitness theory shows that altruism is favored by natural selection if it directly or indirectly benefits the social group of the altruist, or if this social investment eventually benefits the altruist in the future. This mechanism is shown to work smoothly with simulations (Jaffe 2002a, 2004b). Extant instincts and behavior in all plants and animals, including humans, are the product of natural selection. Extending these insights in building economic utility functions helps to understand behaviors that maximize individual benefits directly and indirectly through assortation and synergistic interactions. By doing this, EIFT explains features of modern life that has escaped explanations based on classical economic theory. Terrorism for example is a feature that is ever more important in contemporary society. Motivations to commit terrorist acts, however, are driven by both, biological and economic stimuli. The branch of biology studying animal and human behavior, ethology, tells us that aggression enhances group cohesion, that poor odds of survival or of alternative routes to increase ones fitness (or utility) function increase the likelihood of aggressive interactions, and that large differences in individual strength, or low odds of retaliation, favor aggression (Lorenz 1963; Eibl-Eibesfeldt 1979). The consequences of a behavior determine its evolutionary success. The economic view tells us that the consequences of a behavioral action can be assessed by the ratio of benefits (b) to costs (c). EIFT shows that if b/c is high, even if b is dependent on a network of feed-back mechanisms, biological and economic evolution will favor this behavior. Sometimes, b tends to infinity allowing for the existence of supernormal stimuli (Tinbergen and Perdeck 1950; Mirás et al. 2007). Religion strongly favors such super-stimuli as shown by simulations (Jaffe and Zaballa 2009, 2010). Relatively very large material benefits also induce supernormal motivations (Levitt et al. 2006). Thus, when pursuing heavens, avoiding hell or aiming at paradise on earth, expected benefits tend to infinity. These irrational aims are a consequence of a simplified utility maximization function selected by evolution. If human dreams extend the benefits of its actions to life after death, self-immolation and extreme heroism may become an economically rational choice. These motivations, together with technological means that allow a single individual to inflict harm to many people, and to create diffusely defined but strongly inter-linked groups, allow terrorism to prosper. Modern communication helps creating fantasies that are disconnect with every day reality, favoring these extreme b/c scenarios. Religion helps, but is not necessary in achieving these dreams. This bio-economic view suggests that terrorism might be dealt with better by influencing the perceptions of the benefit/cost balance in the extended utility function. That is, perceived benefits of aggressive ants have to be reduced and cost increased, and benefits of alternative behaviors have to be increased and their costs decreased. By doing this, terrorism motivated by religion (Jaffe and Zaballa 2009) can be shown to be very different from that motivated by politics, illegal business or individual grievances. This insight improves our understanding of the emotions of potential terrorist and the role of inclusive groups, eventually reducing social aggressions by other means than by responding with more violence.

These examples show how a synthetic view of the dynamics governing cooperation might help achieving a better understanding between biology, sociology, economy, and complex system sciences among others, eventually unleashing synergies that might advance our understanding of nature in important ways. Low hanging fruits might be found by economist exploring the working of assortation, which might improve our scant understanding of the interactions between family and business (The Economist 2015). Homophily in human society achieves less diverse but more harmonious economies (Wang and Steiner 2015), suggesting a role for assortation hitherto overlooked in economics. Assortation, viewed in the light of the present theory might, for example, explain the ubiquity of corruption among human societies, and help biologists to better understand economic synergies found in the social phenomena they study, opening our interdisciplinary world view in a consilient way.

Conclusion

There is a common dynamics that drives evolution in biology and in economics. This dynamics allows achieving synergies in the interaction of agents (individuals, organisms or economic entities), in part through the use of assortements in the interactions. An extended Inclusive Fitness Theory allows to develop a language, able to bridge gaps between economic and biological theory. However, the main insight from this review is that the emergence of synergies is an important phenomena that requires deeper studies en biology, economics and in other sciences.

References

  • Allen B, Nowak MA, Wilson EO (2013) Limitations of inclusive fitness. PNAS 110:20135–20139

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alvarez L, Jaffe K (2004) Narcissism guides mate selection: humans mate assortatively, as revealed by facial resemblance, following an algorithm of “self seeking like”. Evolutionary Psychol 2:177–194

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andersson S, Andersson M (1998) Ultraviolet sexual dimorphism and assortative mating in blue tits. Proc R Soc Lond B Biol Sci 265(1395):445–450

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Apicella CL, Marlowe FW, Fowler JH, Christakis NA (2012) Social networks and cooperation in hunter-gatherers. Nature 481(7382):497–501

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aristotle (IV BC) Politics: a treatise on Government. Project Gutenberg. http://www.gutenberg.org/ebooks/6762. Accessed 5 July 2016

  • Axelrod RM (1997) The complexity of cooperation: agent-based models of competition and collaboration. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Axelrod R, Hamilton W (1981) The evolution of cooperation. Science 211:1390–1396

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baranski B, Bartz-Beielstein T, Ehlers R, Kajendran T, Kosslers B, Mehnen J, Polaszek T, Reimholz R, Schmidt J, Schmitt K, Seis D, Slodzinski R, Steeg S, Wiemann N, Zimmermann M (2006) High-Order punishment and the evolution of cooperation. Proc Genetic Evolutionary Comput Conf 2006:379–380

    Google Scholar 

  • Barker JL, Barclay P, Reeve HK (2013) Competition over personal resources favors contribution to shared resources in human groups. PLoS ONE 8(3):e58826. doi:10.1371/journal.pone.0058826

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker GS, Murphy KM (1994) The division of labor, coordination costs, and knowledge. In: Human capital: a theoretical and empirical analysis with special reference to education (3rd edn) Editor: Gary S. Becker, pp 299–322

  • Beinhocker ED (2006) The origin of wealth—evolution, complexity, and the radical remaking of economics. Harvard Business School Press, Boston

    Google Scholar 

  • Bettencourt LMA (2013) The origins of scaling in Cities. Science 340:1438–1441

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Birch J, Okasha S (2015) Kin selection and its critics. BioScience 65:22–32

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bonabeau E (2002) Agent-based modeling: methods and techniques for simulating human systems. Proc Natl Acad Sci 99(Suppl 3):7280–7287

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bourke AFG (2011) Principles of social evolution. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Bourke AF (2014) Hamilton’s rule and the causes of social evolution. Phil Trans R Soc B 369:1471–2970

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bowles S, Gintis H (2005) Can self-interest explain cooperation? Evolutionary Inst Econ Rev 2(1):21–41

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bradley M, Desai A, Kim EH (1983) The rationale behind interfirm tender offers: information or synergy? J Financ Econ 11(1):183–206

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bronstein JL (1994) Our current understanding of mutualism. Q Rev Biol 1:31–51

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Centola D, Gonzalez-Avella JC, Eguiluz VM, San Miguel M (2007) Homophily, cultural drift, and the co-evolution of cultural groups. J Conflict Resolut 51(6):905–929

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chatterjee S (1986) Types of synergy and economic value: the impact of acquisitions on merging and rival firms. Strateg Manag J 7:119–139

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Christakis NA, Fowler JH (2014) Friendship and natural selection. PNAS 1400825111

  • Chuang JS, Rivoire O, Leibler S (2010) Cooperation and Hamilton’s rule in a simple synthetic microbial system. Mol Syst Biol 6(1):398

    Google Scholar 

  • Cooke F, Finney GH, Rockwell RF (1976) Assortative mating in lesser snow geese (Anser caerulescens). Behav Genet 6(2):127–140

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corning PA (1983) The synergism hypothesis: a theory of progressive evolution. McGraw-Hill, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Corning PA (2007) Synergy goes to war: a bioeconomic theory of collective violence. J Bioecon 9.2:109–144

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corning PA (2013) Rotating the Necker cube: a bioconomic approach to cooperation and the causal role of synergy in evolution. J Bioecon 15:171–193

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corning PA, Szathmáry E (2015) ‘Synergistic selection’: a Darwinian frame for the evolution of complexity. J Theor Biol 371:45–58

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crespi BJ (2001) The evolution of social behavior in microorganisms. Trends Ecol Evol 16:178–183

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Darwin C (1859) On the origin of species by means of natural selection. http://ns1.ias.ac.in/resonance/Volumes/14/02/0204-0208.pdf

  • Dawkins R (1989) The selfish gene (2nd edn). Oxford University Press, Oxford, p 192. ISBN 0-19-286092-5

  • Dawkins R, Krebs JR (1979) Arms races between and within species. Proc R Soc Lond B Biol Sci 205(1161):489–511

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dobzhansky T (1970) Genetics of the evolutionary process, vol 139. Columbia University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Dolfsma W, Soete L (eds) (2006) Understanding the dynamics of a knowledge economy. Edward Elgar Publishing, Cheltenham

    Google Scholar 

  • Dopfer K (1991) Toward a theory of economic institutions: synergy and path dependency. J Econ Issues 25(2):535–550

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Durrett R, Levin SA (2005) Can stable social groups be maintained by homophilous imitation alone? J Econ Behav Organ 57(3):267–286

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eibl-Eibesfeldt I (1979) Biology of peace and war. Thames and Hudson, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Eigen M (1971) Selforganization of matter and the evolution of biological macromolecules. Naturwissenschaften 58(10):465–523

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Epstein JM (2006) Generative social science: studies in agent-based computational modeling. Princeton University Press, Macromolecules. Naturwissenschaften 58(10):465–523

    Google Scholar 

  • Eun CS, Kolodny R, Scheraga C (1996) Cross-border acquisitions and shareholder wealth: tests of the synergy and internalization hypotheses. J Bank Finance 20(9):1559–1582

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Evans P (1996) Government action, social capital and development: reviewing the evidence on synergy. World Dev 24(6):1119–1132

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ferrante E, Turgut AE, Duéñez-Guzmán E, Dorigo M, Wenseleers T (2015) Evolution of self-organized task specialization in robot swarms. PLoS Comput Biol 11(8):e1004273

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fisher RA (1958) The genetical theory of natural selection, 2nd edn. Dover, New York

  • Fletcher JA, Doebeli M (2006) How altruism evolves: assortment and synergy. J Evol Biol 19:1389–1393

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Florida R (2005) Cities and the creative class. Routledge, Abingdon-on-Thames

    Google Scholar 

  • Fu F, Nowak MA, Christakis NA, Fowler JH (2012) The evolution of homophily. Sci Rep 3:845

    Google Scholar 

  • Fuller RB (1975) Synergetics. Pacific Tape Library, pp 372–434

  • Gadagkar R, Gadagkar R (2009) The social biology of Ropalidia marginata: toward understanding the evolution of eusociality. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Gardner A, West AA, Wild G (2011) The genetical theory of kin selection. J Evol Biol 24:1020–1043

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Georgescu-Roegen N (1970) The economics of production. Am Econ Rev 60(2):1–9

    Google Scholar 

  • Grafen A, Archetti M (2008) Natural selection of altruism in inelastic viscous homogeneous populations. J Theor Biol 252:694–710

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grant RM (1991) The resource-based theory of competitive advantage: implications for strategy formulation. Calif Manag Rev 33(3):114–135

  • Hadzibeganovic T, Lima FWS, Stauffer D (2014) Benefits of memory for the evolution of tag-based cooperation in structured populations. Behav Ecol Sociobiol 68:1059–1072

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haken H (1973) Introduction to synergetics. In: Synergetics. Vieweg + Teubner Verlag, pp 9–19

  • Haken H, Portugali J (2003) The face of the city is its information. J Environ Psychol 23(4):385–408

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haldane JBS (1932) The causes of evolution. Harper & Row, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton WD (1963) The evolution of altruistic behavior. Am Nat 97(896):354–356

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton WD (1964) The genetical evolution of social behaviour I and II. J Theor Biol 7:1–52

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton WD (1971) Geometry for the selfish herd. J Theor Biol 31(2):295–311

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton WD (1975) Innate social aptitudes of man: an approach from evolutionary genetics. In: Fox R (ed) Biosocial anthropology. Malaby Press, London, pp 133–153

    Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton WD (1996) Narrow roads of gene land, volume 1: evolution of social behavior. Oxford University Press, Oxford

  • Hamilton IM, Taborsky M (2005) Contingent movement and cooperation evolve under generalized reciprocity. Proc R Soc B Biol Sci 272(1578):2259–2267

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harcombe W (2010) Novel cooperation experimentally evolved between species. Evolution 64(7):2166–2172

    Google Scholar 

  • Hauert C, Michor F, Nowak MA, Doebeli M (2006) Synergy and discounting of cooperation in social dilemmas. J Theor Biol 239:195–202

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hausmann R, Hidalgo CA (2014) The atlas of economic complexity: mapping paths to prosperity. MIT Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek F (1949) Individualism and economic order. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Hoeksema JD, Bruna EM (2000) Pursuing the big questions about interspecific mutualism: a review of theoretical approaches. Oecologia 125(3):321–330

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hofbauer J, Sigmund K (2003) Evolutionary game dynamics. Bull Am Math Soc 40:479

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hölldobler B, Wilson EO (2009) The super organism. Norton & Co., New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Humboldt A (1807) Le voyage aux régions equinoxiales du Nouveau Continent, fait en 1799–1804, par Alexandre de Humboldt et Aimé Bonpland. Paris

  • Huxley J (1942) Evolution. The modern synthesis

  • Itô Y (1993) Behaviour and social evolution of wasps: the communal aggregation hypothesis. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Ivens ABF (2014) Cooperation and conflict in ant (Hymenoptera: Formicidae) farming mutualisms—a review. Myrmecol News 21:19–36

    Google Scholar 

  • Jaffe K (1996) The dynamics of the evolution of sex: Why the sexes are, in fact, always two? Interciencia, 21:259–267, 22:48

  • Jaffe K (2001) On the relative importance of Haplo-Diploidy, assortative mating, and social synergy in the evolution of social behaviour. Acta Biotheor 49:29–42

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jaffe K (2002a) An economic analysis of altruism. Who benefits from altruistic acts? J Artif Soc Soc Simul 5:3

    Google Scholar 

  • Jaffe K (2002b) On sex, mate selection and evolution: an exploration. Comments Theor Biol 7(2):91–107

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jaffe K (2004a) Sex promotes gamete selection: a quantitative comparative study of features favoring the evolution of sex. Complexity 9(6):43–51

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jaffe K (2004b) Altruism, altruistic punishment and decentralized social investment. Acta Biotheor 52:155–172

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jaffe K (2008) On the adaptive value of sex. In: Unifying themes in complex systems IV. Springer, Berlin, pp 213–221

  • Jaffe K (2009) What is science? An interdisciplinary perspective. University Press of America, Lanham

    Google Scholar 

  • Jaffe K (2010) Quantifying social synergy in insect and human societies. Behav Ecol Sociobiol 64:1721–1724

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jaffe K (2014a) The wealth of nations: complexity science for an interdisciplinary approach in economics, Amazon books

  • Jaffe K (2014b) Social and natural sciences differ in their research strategies, adapted to work for different knowledge landscapes. PLoS ONE 9(11):e113901

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jaffe K (2015) Visualizing the invisible hand of markets: simulating complex dynamic economic interactions. Jaffe K. Intelligent systems in accounting, finance and management 2015 (in press, see ArXiv 1412.6924)

  • Jaffe K, Cipriani R (2007) Culture outsmarts nature in the evolution of cooperation. JASSS 10/1/7

  • Jaffe K, da Silva ER (2002) Expanded food choice as a possible factor in the evolution of sociality of Vespidae (Hymenoptera). Sociobiology 39:1–12

    Google Scholar 

  • Jaffe K, Febres G (2016) Defining synergy thermodynamically using quantitative measurements of entropy and free energy. Complexity (in press)

  • Jaffe K, Fonck C (1994) Energetics of social phenomena: physics applied to evolutionary biology. Il Nuovo Cimento 16:543–553

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jaffe K, Hebling-Beraldo MJ (1993) Oxygen consumption and the evolution of order: negentropy criteria applied to the evolution of ants. Experientia 49:587–592

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jaffe K, Levy-Carciente S (2004) Simulating barter, money and financial economies. http://atta.labb.usb.ve/Klaus/art156b.pdf

  • Jaffe K, Osborn F (2004) Simulation of coevolution in batesian mimicry. Naturalia 28:9–18

    Google Scholar 

  • Jaffe K, Perez E (1989) Comparative study of brain morphology in ants. Brain Behav Evol 33(1):25–33

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jaffe K, Zaballa L (2009) Cooperative punishment and religion’s role in the evolution of prosocial altruism. In: Feierman JR (ed) Chapter 13 in: the biology of religious behavior: the evolutionary origins of faith and religion. Praeger

  • Jaffe K, Zaballa L (2010) Co-operative punishment cements social cohesion. J Artif Soc Soc Simul 13(3):4

    Google Scholar 

  • Jaffe K, Florez A, Grigorieva V, Masciti M, Castro I (2010) Comparing skills and attitudes of scientists, musicians, politicians and students. Interciencia 35(7):545–552

    Google Scholar 

  • Jaffe K, Rios A, Florez A (2013a) Statistics shows that economic prosperity needs both high scientific productivity and complex technological knowledge, but in different ways. Interciencia 38:150–156

    Google Scholar 

  • Jaffe K, Caicedo M, Manzanares M, Rios A, Florez A, Montoreano C, Davila V (2013b) Productivity in physical and chemical science predicts the future economic growth of developing countries better than other indices for knowledge. PloS One 0066239

  • Jaffe K, Flórez A, Manzanares M, Jaffe R, Gomes CM, Rodríguez D, Achury C (2014) On the bioeconomics of shame and guilt. J Bioecon 1–13. doi:10.1007/s10818-014-9189-5

  • Kenrick DT, Griskevicius V, Sundie JM, Li NP, Li YJ, Neuberg SL (2009) Deep rationality: the evolutionary economics of decision making. social cognition: vol. 27, Special Issue: Rationality Restored, pp 764–785

  • Kiers ET, West SA (2015) Evolving new organisms via symbiosis. Science 348:392–394

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kim J (2010) A tag-based evolutionary prisoner’s dilemma game on networks with different topologies. J Artif Soc Soc Simul 13:3

    Google Scholar 

  • Kossinets G, Watts DJ (2009) Origins of homophily in an evolving social network. Am J Sociol 115(2):405–450

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krotopkin P (1902) El apoyo mutuo (1989). Ediciones Madre Tierra. Madrid (España)

  • Kuperman MN, Risau-Gusman S (2012) Relationship between clustering coefficient and the success of cooperation in networks. Phys Rev E 86:016104

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Larsson R, Finkelstein S (1999) Integrating strategic, organizational, and human resource perspectives on mergers and acquisitions: a case survey of synergy realization. Organ Sci 10(1):1–26

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levitt SD, Stephen J, Dubner DJ (2006) Freakonomics: a rogue economist explores the hidden side of everything. HarperCollins, NY

    Google Scholar 

  • Lewicki RJ, Saunders DM, Barry B (1985) Negotiation. Irwin, Homewood, pp 166–169

    Google Scholar 

  • Liu HB, Huang ZH (2007) An empirical research on the synergy effects in the integration of industry chains—the perspective of circular economy theory. J Technol Econ 9:007

    Google Scholar 

  • Lorenz K (1963) Das Sogenannte Böse, Zur Naturgeschichte der Aggression first published 1963 by Verlag Dr Borotha-Schoeler, Vienna, Austria. English version: (2002). On aggression. Psychology Press, Milton Park

  • Marx K (1867) Das Kapital. DC books (2008)

  • Massen JJM, Koski SE (2014) Chimps of a feather sit together: chimpanzee friendships are based on homophily in personality. Evolution and Human Behavior 35(1):1–8

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maynard Smith J (1983) Models of evolution. Proc R Soc B 219:315–325

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maynard-Smith J (1964) Group selection and kin selection. Nature 4924:1145–1147

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mayr E (1963) Animal species and evolution. Animal species and their evolution. Google Books

  • Michener CD (1969) Comparative social behavior of bees. Ann Rev Entomol 14:299–342

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mirás B, Cabrera A, Jaffe K (2007) Mate selection in the moth Neoleucinodes elegantalis: evidence for a supernormal chemical stimulus in sexual attraction. Anim Behav 73:727–734

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Montoreano C, Jaffe K (2013) Relative importance of social synergy, assortation and networks in the evolution of social cooperation. http://arxiv.org/abs/1311.4407

  • Nowak MA (2006) Five rules for the evolution of cooperation. Science 314:1560–1563

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nowak MA, May R (1993) The spatial dilemmas of evolution. Int J Bifurc Chaos 3:35–78

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nowak MA, Sigmund K (1998) The dynamic of indirect reciprocity. J Theor Biol 194:561–574

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nowak MA, Sigmund K (2005) Evolution of indirect reciprocity. Nature 437:1291–1298

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nowak MA, Tarnita CE, Wilson EO (2010) The evolution of eusociality. Nature 446:1057–1062

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ochoa G, Jaffe K (2006) Assortative mating drastically alters the magnitude of error thresholds. Lecture Notes in Computer Science LNCS 4193, Parallel Problem Solving from Nature—PPSN IX. Editors: Runarsson et al. Springer, Berlin, pp 890–899

  • Ohtsuki H, Hauert C, Lieberman E, Nowak M (2006) A simple rule for the evolution of cooperation on graphs and social networks. Nature 441:502–505

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Osborn F, Jaffe K (1997) Cooperation vs. exploitation: interactions between Lycaenid (Lepidopera: Lycaenidae) larvae and ants. J Res Lepid 34:69–82

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom E (1996) Crossing the great divide: coproduction, synergy, and development. World Dev 24(6):1073–1087

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Payne C, Jaffe K (2005) Self seeks like: many humans choose their dog-pets following rules used for assortative mating. J Ethol 23(1):15–18

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pepper JW, Smuts BB (2000) The evolution of cooperation in an ecological context: an agent-based model. Oxford University Press, New York, pp 45–76

    Google Scholar 

  • Porter ME (2011) Competitive advantage of nations: creating and sustaining superior performance. Simon and Schuster, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Price GR (1970) Selection and covariance. Nature 227:520–521

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Price GR (1971) Extension of the Hardy-Weinberg law to assortative mating. Ann Hum Genet 35(4):485–490

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Queller DC (1985) Kinship, reciprocity, and synergism in the evolution of social behavior. Nature 318:366–367

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Queller DC (1992) A general model for kin selection. Evolution 46:376–380

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Queller DC (2011) Expanded social fitness and Hamilton´s rule for kin, kith, and kind. PNAS 108:10792–10799

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ricardo D (1891) Principles of political economy and taxation. George Bell and sons, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Riolo R, Cohen M, Axelrod R (2001) Evolution of cooperation without reciprocity. Nature 414:441–443

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Segerstrale U (2013) Nature’s oracle: the life and work of WD Hamilton. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Seinen I, Schram A (2006) Social status and group norms: indirect reciprocity in a helping experiment. Eur Econ Rev 50:581–602

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Silva ER, Jaffe K (2002) Expanded food choice as a possible factor in the evolution of eusociality in Vespidae. Sociobiology 39:25–36

    Google Scholar 

  • Skyrms B, Avise JC, Ayala FJ (2014) In the light of evolution VIII: darwinian thinking in the social sciences. PNAS 111:10781–10784

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith A (1776) The wealth of nations. The Modern Library, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith J, Van Dyken JD, ZeeJune PC (2010) A generalization of Hamilton’s rule for the evolution of microbial cooperation. Science 328:1700–1703

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stilling RM, Bordenstein SR, Dinan TG, Cryan JF (2014) Friends with social benefits: host-microbe interactions as a driver of brain evolution and development? Front Cell Infect Microbiol 4:147

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Strassmann JE, Queller DC, Solis CR, Hughes CR (1991) Relatedness and queen number in the Neotropical wasp. Parachartergus colobopterus. Anim Behav 42(3):461–470

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taylor PD (2013) Inclusive and personal fitness in synergistic evolutionary games on graphs. J Theor Biol 21:76–82

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tesfatsion L, Judd KL (eds) (2006) Handbook of computational economics: agent-based computational economics, vol 2. Elsevier, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • The Economist (2015) Family companies: to have and to hold. April 18. The Economist Newspaper Limited

  • Tinbergen N, Perdeck A (1950) On the stimulus situation releasing the begging response in the newly hatched herring gull chick (Larus a. argentatus Pont). Behaviour 3:1–38

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tollefson J (2015) Can randomized trials eliminate global poverty? Nature 524:150–153

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van Cleve J, Akcay E (2014) Pathways to social evolution: reciprocity, relatedness, and synergy. Evolution 3(68):2245–2258

    Google Scholar 

  • Wallace AR (1870) Contributions to the theory of natural selection. Google Books

  • Wang C, Steiner B (2015) Can ethno-linguistic diversity explain cross-country differences in social capital? A global perspective. Econ Rec. doi:10.1111/1475-4932.12195

    Google Scholar 

  • Weisel O, Shalvi S (2015) The collaborative roots of corruption. PNAS 112:10651–10656

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wilson EO (1999) Consilience. Vintage Books, 1999

  • Wilson EO (2000) Sociobiology: the new synthesis. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Woolley AW, Chabris CF, Pentland A, Hashmi N, Malone TW (2010) Evidence for a collective intelligence factor in the performance of human groups. Science 330:686–688

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zaman L, Meyer JR, Devangam S, Bryson DM, Lenski RE et al (2014) Coevolution drives the emergence of complex traits and promotes evolvability. PLoS Biol 12(12):e1002023. doi:10.1371/journal.pbio.1002023

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zimmerman M, Eguíluz V, San Miguel M, Spadaro A (2000) Cooperation in an adaptive network. Adv Complex Syst 3:283–297

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Authors’ contributions

KJ conceived the ideas, analyzed the data, paid for all the expenses and wrote the paper.

Acknowledgements

Thanks are due to Michael Hrncir, Cristina Sainz, Emilio Herrera, Rodolfo Jaffe, and Peer 1038 of Peerage of Science. The paper was written as a response to questions and discussions triggered by my plenary talk honoring the 50 years of Bill Hamilton Inclusive Fitness Theory at the International Ethology meeting organized by the Sociedade Brasileira de Etologia in Mossoro in 2014. A non-quantifiable number of people helped crystallize the ideas presented during the last few decades. These include long evenings with Bill Hamilton during the eighties in the Americas and later in his house in Oxford; intensive conversations with John Maynard Smith in the University of Sussex a few months before his death; conversations and correspondence with David Queller; suggestions from Peter Corning; among many others. I thank Springer Verlag for waiving my fees for this publication; the total ignorance of the working of synergy in the modern world by Venezuela’s regime during the last 18 years has collapsed its institutions and economy, making the financing of science all but impossible.

Competing interests

The author declares that he has no competing interests.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Klaus Jaffe.

Rights and permissions

Open Access This article is distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons license, and indicate if changes were made.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Jaffe, K. Extended inclusive fitness theory: synergy and assortment drives the evolutionary dynamics in biology and economics. SpringerPlus 5, 1092 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1186/s40064-016-2750-z

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1186/s40064-016-2750-z

Keywords